82 CLMLR 1600 |
Page
|
(Cite as: 82 Colum. L. Rev. 1600) |
Columbia Law Review
December, 1982
*1600 FAIR USE AS MARKET FAILURE: A STRUCTURAL AND ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE
BETAMAX CASE AND ITS PREDECESSORS
Wendy J. Gordon [FNa1]
Copyright © 1982 by Wendy J. Gordon
I. COPYRIGHTS AND MARKETS
II. THE THREE PART TEST FOR DETERMINING FAIR USE
III. EVIDENCE OF A MARKET APPROACH IN EXISTING AUTHORITIES
IV. CASE STUDIES FOR FAIR-USE ANALYSIS
The court's evaluation of harm to plaintiff is also questionable in some respects. In particular, the court refused to include in its assessment of plaintiff's injury the potential photocopy royalty income that the plaintiff might have received if its copyright were enforced. The court wrote:
It is wrong to measure the detriment to plaintiff by loss of presumed royalty income--a standard which necessarily assumes that plaintiff had a right to issue licenses. That would be true, of course, only if it were first decided that the defendant's practices did not constitute "fair use." In determining whether the company has been sufficiently hurt to cause these practices to become "unfair," one cannot assume at the start the merit of the plaintiff's position . . . . [FN284]
CONCLUSION
[FN1]. 659 F.2d 963 (9th Cir.1981), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687).
[FN2]. Id. at 969.[FN3]. Dellar v. Samuel Goldwyn, Inc., 104 F.2d 661, 662 (2d Cir.1939) (per curiam). The complexity of the issues underlying fair use has been recognized since its inception. See, e.g., Folsom v. Marsh, 9 F. Cas. 342, 344-45 (C.C.D.Mass.1841) (No. 4901).
[FN4]. Universal City Studios, 659 F.2d at 970; see also id. at 971 (new technology strains the fair use doctrine in removing control of access from the author). The court relied there on a thoughtful work by Leon Seltzer. Seltzer, Exemptions and Fair Use in Copyright: The "Exclusive Rights" Tensions in the New Copyright Act, 24 Bull. Copyright Soc'y 215 (1977), reprinted in L. Seltzer, Exemptions and Fair Use In Copyright (1978).
[FN5]. 487 F.2d 1345 (Ct. Cl. 1973), aff'd by an equally divided court, 420 U.S. 376 (1975) (per curiam).
[FN6]. 420 U.S. 376 (1975) (per curiam).
[FN7]. The Williams & Wilkins opinion is discussed infra notes 249-88 and accompanying text.
[FN8]. Sony Corp. of America v. Universal City Studios, Inc., 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687.
[FN9]. This Article will analyze critically certain aspects of the Court of Claims's opinion, see infra notes 260-88 and accompanying text. Other aspects of the opinion have been the subject of much analysis. See, e.g., Nimmer, Photocopying and Record Piracy: Of Dred Scott and Alice in Wonderland, 22 U.C.L.A.L.Rev. 1052 (1975).
[FN10]. "[S]ince the doctrine is an equitable rule of reason, no generally applicable definition is possible, and each case raising the question must be decided on its own facts." H.R.Rep. No. 1476, 94th Cong., 2d Sess. 65 (1976) [hereinafter cited as House Report], reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News 5659, 5679. In 1961, the then Register of Copyrights described fair use as follows: "'[F]air use' . . . eludes precise definition; broadly speaking, it means that a reasonable portion of a copyrighted work may be reproduced without permission when necessary for a legitimate purpose which is not competitive with the copyright owner's market for his work." Staff of House Comm. on the Judiciary, 87th Cong., 1st Sess., Copyright Law Revision, Report of the Register of Copyrights on the General Revision of the U.S. Copyright Law 24 (Comm. Print 1961). Another often quoted definition is that fair use is a "privilege in others than the owner of a copyright to use the copyrighted material in a reasonable manner without his consent, notwithstanding the monopoly granted to the owner." H. Ball, The Law of Copyright and Literary Property 260 (1944).
[FN11]. See infra text accompanying notes 89-91 & 150-98.
[FN12]. See infra text accompanying notes 92-103 & 199-240.
[FN13]. See infra text accompanying notes 104-24 & 241-47.
[FN14]. See infra text accompanying notes 295-307.
[FN15]. See infra notes 150-240 & 295-97 and accompanying text.
[FN16]. See infra text accompanying notes 249-88.
[FN17]. See infra text accompanying notes 289-322.
[FN18]. U.S. Const. art. I, § 8, cl. 8.
[FN19]. For an overview of copyright history, see B. Kaplan, An Unhurried View of Copyright 1-38 (1967); A. Latman & R. Gorman, Copyright for the Eighties 1-10 (1981).
[FN20]. See, e.g., Mazer v. Stein, 347 U.S. 201, 219 (1954).
[FN21]. See, e.g., Rosemont Enter., Inc. v. Random House, Inc., 366 F.2d 303, 307 (2d Cir.1966), cert. denied, 385 U.S. 1009 (1967). The current debates on fair use do not attack this general principle, but center on the extent to which the incentive purpose requires enforcement of the author's right "to control the cost of and access to" his production in varying circumstances. Universal City Studios v. Sony Corp. of America, 659 F.2d 963, 965 (9th Cir.1981), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687).
[FN22]. The Federalist No. 43, at 272 (J. Madison) (C. Rossiter ed. 1961).
[FN23]. See, e.g., Rosemont Enter., Inc. v. Random House, Inc., 366 F.2d 303, 306-07 (2d Cir.1966), cert. denied, 385 U.S. 1009 (1967); Triangle Publications, Inc. v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers, Inc., 626 F.2d 1171, 1173-75 (5th Cir.1980).
[FN24]. See generally B. Kaplan, supra note 19.
[FN25]. Universal City Studios v. Sony Corp. of America, 659 F.2d 963, 969 (9th Cir.1981) (quoting Dellar v. Samuel Goldwyn, Inc., 104 F.2d 661 (2d Cir.1939)), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687).
[FN26]. The doctrine of fair use was first accorded statutory recognition in the 1976 revision of the Copyright Act. The statute provides: § 107. Limitations on exclusive rights: Fair use Notwithstanding the provisions of section 106, the fair use of a copyrighted work, including such use by reproduction in copies or phonorecords or by any other means specified by that section, for purposes such as criticism, comment, news reporting, teaching (including multiple copies for classroom use), scholarship, or research, is not an infringement of copyright. In determining whether the use made of a work in any particular case is a fair use the factors to be considered shall include-- (1) the purpose and character of the use, including whether such use is of a commercial nature or is for nonprofit educational purposes; (2) the nature of the copyrighted work; (3) the amount and substantiality of the portion used in relation to the copyrighted work as a whole; and (4) the effect of the use upon the potential market for or value of the copyrighted work. 17 U.S.C. § 107 (1976). The legislative history of § 107 of the 1976 Copyright Act indicates that, despite the statutory recognition accorded fair use, the nature of the doctrine remains to be defined by case law: "The bill endorses the purpose and general scope of the judicial doctrine of fair use, but there is no disposition to freeze the doctrine in the statute . . . ." House Report, supra note 10, at 66, reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News at 5680. See also S.Rep. No. 473, 94th Cong., 1st Sess. 62 (1975) [hereinafter cited as Senate Report]. The courts have recognized their freedom to continue the development of fair use doctrine. See, e.g., Triangle Publications, Inc. v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers, Inc., 626 F.2d 1171, 1174 (5th Cir.1980) ("Congress made clear that it in no way intended to depart from Court-created principles or to short- circuit further judicial development . . . .").
[FN27]. 17 U.S.C. § 107 (1976).
[FN28]. House Report, supra note 10, at 65, reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News at 5679.
[FN29]. The 1976 Copyright Act provides that "[i]n determining whether the use . . . is a fair use the factors to be considered shall include" those factors listed in the text. 17 U.S.C. § 107 (1976). The Act provides that the term "including" is "illustrative and not limitative." Id. § 101. See also House Report, supra note 10, at 66, reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News at 5681-83 ("Beyond a very broad statutory explanation of what fair use is and some of the criteria applicable to it, the courts must be free to adapt the doctrine to particular situations on a case-by-case basis."). The Fifth Circuit recognized the open-ended nature of the statute, but also indicated that "normally these four factors would govern the analysis." Triangle Publications, Inc. v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers, Inc., 626 F.2d 1171, 1175 n.10 (5th Cir.1980).
[FN30]. See supra note 26.
[FN31]. The courts have reached varying results on these questions. The Fifth Circuit, for example, recognized that "[t]he statute does not indicate how much weight is to be accorded each factor" but considered "the fourth factor, the effect of the use upon the potential market for or the value of the copyrighted work" to be the most important. Triangle Publications, Inc. v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers, Inc., 626 F.2d 1171, 1175 (5th Cir.1980). Other courts have placed much emphasis on the amount and substantiality of the portion copied (the third factor). The Triangle opinion stated that "the idea that the copying of an entire copyrighted work can never be fair use 'is an overbroad generalization, unsupported by the decisions and rejected by years of accepted practice."' Id. at 1177 n.15 (quoting Williams & Wilkins Co. v. United States, 487 F.2d 1345, 1353, 203 Ct.Cl. 74 (1973), aff'd by an equally divided court, 420 U.S. 376 (1975) (per curiam) (citing cases)) (reproduction of copyrighted magazine covers in competitor's comparative advertisements held to be fair use). The district court in the Betamax case took a similar position, in its functional approach to substantiality. See Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 480 F.Supp. 429, 454- 56 (C.D.Cal. 1979), rev'd in part and remanded 659 F.2d 963 (9th Cir.1981), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687). See also the "Agreement on Guidelines for Classroom Copying in Not-For-Profit Educational Institutions." House Report, supra note 10, at 68-70, reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News at 5681-83 (copying of "complete poem," "complete article, story, or essay" will be fair use if other conditions are met). By contrast, the Ninth Circuit intimated that it weighed the quantity of copying quite heavily, regardless of its functional impact. Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 659 F.2d 963, 973 (9th Cir.1981), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687). Congress took the position that, "[T]he endless variety of situations and combinations of circumstances that can rise [sic] in particular cases precludes the formulation of exact rules in the statute." House Report, supra note 10, at 65-66, reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News at 5675-80.
[FN32]. Thomas C. Schelling has written: A good part of social organization--of what we call society--consists of institutional arrangements to overcome . . . divergences between perceived individual interest and some larger collective bargain. Some of it is market- oriented--ownership, contracts, damage suits, patents and copyrights, promissory notes, rental agreements, and a variety of communications and information systems. Some have to do with government--taxes to cover public services, protection of persons, a weather bureau if weather information is not otherwise marketable, one-way streets, laws against littering, wrecking crews to clear away that car in the southbound lane and policemen to wave us on in the northbound lane. More selective groupings--the union, the club, the neighborhood--can organize incentive systems or regulations to try to help people do what individually they wouldn't but collectively they may wish to do. Our morals can substitute for markets and regulations, in getting us sometimes to do from conscience the things that in the long run we might elect to do only if assured of reciprocation. T. Schelling, Micromotives and Macrobehavior 127-28 (1978).
[FN33]. See generally R. Posner, Economic Analysis of Law 11-12 (2d ed. 1977). Market failure, its effect on economic efficiency, and the variety of available cures are recurrent themes in Judge Posner's text. Some significant forms of allocative inefficiency are reviewed in Markovitz, The Causes and Policy Significance of Pareto Resource Misallocation: A Checklist for Micro- Economic Policy Analysis, 28 Stan.L.Rev. 1 (1975).
[FN34]. See, e.g., G. Calabresi & P. Bobbitt, Tragic Choices 31-34 (1978).
[FN35]. See generally R. Heilbroner, The Worldly Philosophers 49-72 (5th ed. 1980); A. Smith, Wealth of Nations (E. Canaan ed. 1937). Some argue that a market economy also helps to protect and nurture political freedoms. See, e.g., M. Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom 7-36 (1962).
[FN36]. In the examples that follow, "value" will be explored predominantly in terms of how a resource user can serve consumer desires. It should not be forgotten, however, that serving one's own needs also has value in the economic sense. A person's willingness to pay to use an item for personal consumption reflects "social benefit" since each person is a member of society. Also, "value," as defined in connection with willingness to pay, see infra text accompanying note 38, is of course dependent, inter alia, on distribution of income, and is at best only an indirect measure of desire and benefit. While an exploration of the limitations and virtues of the "value" criterion is beyond the scope of this Article, it should be noted that courts sometimes use intuitive noneconomic measures of social benefit. See infra note 95 and accompanying text.
[FN37]. Judge Posner explains this process by using the following example: Let Farmer A own a piece of land which he anticipates will yield him $100 a year, in excess of labor and other costs, indefinitely. Just as the price of a share of common stock expresses the present value of the anticipated earnings to which the shareholder will be entitled, so the present value of a parcel of land that is expected to yield an annual net income of $100 can be calculated and is the minimum price that A will accept in exchange for his property right. Suppose Farmer B believes that he can use A's land more productively than A, i.e., that he could net more than $100 a year from working A's land. The present value of B's higher expected earnings stream will, of course, exceed the present value calculated by A. Suppose the present value calculated by A is $1000 and by B $1500. At a price of $1250, for example, A will receive $250 more than the land is worth to him and B will pay $250 less than the land is worth to him. Thus, there are strong incentives for the parties voluntarily to exchange A's land for B's money, and if B is as he believes a better farmer than A, the transfer will result in an increase in the productivity of the land. Through a succession of such transfers, resources are shifted to their most valuable uses and efficiency in the use of economic resources is thereby maximized. R. Posner, supra note 33, at 29 (footnotes omitted).
[FN38]. Id. at 10 (emphasis omitted). Judge Posner defines "efficiency" as the maximization of "value" so measured. Id. Note that under this definition, it is "efficient" to take resources from a person in whose hands they have less "value" and give them to another person in whose hands they have more "value," even if the loser is not compensated for the transfer. Even aside from the general questions that can be raised concerning any quasi-utilitarian measure, the adequacy of Judge Posner's "value" as a test of public welfare has been often questioned. See, e.g., Leff, Economic Analysis of Law: Some Realism About Nominalism, 60 Va.L.Rev. 451, 477-82 (1974); Polinsky, Economic Analysis As a Potentially Defective Product: A Buyer's Guide to Posner's Economic Analysis of Law, 87 Harv.L.Rev. 1655, 1665, 1679-81 (1974). This Article does not argue that maximizing value is a sufficient justification for all instances of fair use; it argues that the copyright owner must be compensated if denying him control over a contested use of his work would cause him substantial injury. See infra text accompanying notes 104-24. See also generally Michelman, Property, Utility, and Fairness: Comments on the Ethical Foundations of "Just Compensation" Law, 80 Harv.L.Rev. 1165 (1967) (evaluating "efficiency" and other criteria in the identification of which of the losses occasioned by governmental activity should be noncompensable and which should be entitled to "just compensation"). The traditional criterion that welfare economics has used for "judging whether resource use is efficient" is the Pareto Condition in which "no reallocation can yield improvement for some without injury to others." D. Orr, Property, Markets and Government Intervention 100 (1976). See infra note 54. See also J. Hadar, Elementary Theory of Microeconomic Behavior 319-45 (2d ed. 1974); N. Singer, Public Microeconomics: An Introduction to Government Finance 81-85 (2d ed. 1976). However, the Pareto Condition, when interpreted strictly, has only limited usefulness as a criterion because "virtually all policies will harm someone." Markovitz, supra note 33, at 2 n.2. Thus, a Posnerian use of an aggregate measure to define efficiency is common among legal scholars. See id. at 2. ("[O]nly rarely does a policy actually move the economy to a Pareto- preferred position. Accordingly, I find it more useful to focus on whether a policy seems likely to give its beneficiaries the equivalent of more dollars than it seems likely to take away from its victims.") (footnotes omitted). See also Calabresi & Melamed, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, 85 Harv.L.Rev. 1089, 1094 (1972) ( "[E]conomic efficiency . . . asks for that form of property, private or communal, which leads to the highest product for the effort of producing.").
[FN39]. There may also be occasions in which it is normatively inappropriate to use even a perfectly functioning market. Similarly, enforcement of an author's market right is arguably inappropriate when such enforcement would threaten nonmonetizable first amendment interests. See infra text accompanying notes 170-73. Some commentators have suggested a separate first amendment exception to copyright, while others have suggested recognition of a first amendment dimension to fair use. For valuable introductions to this literature, see Denicola, Copyright and Free Speech: Constitutional Limitations on the Protection of Expression, 67 Calif.L.Rev. 283 (1979); Goldstein, Copyright and the First Amendment, 70 Colum.L.Rev. 983 (1970).
[FN40]. See D. Orr, supra note 38, at ch. 15 ("Externalities and Public Goods"); Markovitz, supra note 33, at 2. In the absence of transaction costs, this condition will automatically be met, because persons affected by transactions can "bribe" participants within the transactions to take actions in accordance with their interest. See generally Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & Econ. 293 (1970). See R. Posner, supra note 33. See also Markovitz, supra note 33, at 7 n.14.
[FN41]. See infra text accompanying notes 170-76, 182.
[FN42]. See Markovitz, supra note 33, at 2, 3, 7; Polinsky, supra note 38, at 1667. See also J. Hadar, supra note 38, at § 13.4 ("Behavior Under Uncertainty").
[FN43]. See Polinsky, supra note 38, at 1667.
[FN44]. See infra text accompanying note 183, which suggests that reviews and criticisms may be appropriate subjects for fair use treatment in order to protect the availability of such information.
[FN45]. See supra note 37.
[FN46]. Transaction costs are "the costs of effecting a transfer of rights." R. Posner, supra note 33, at 30. Where transaction costs are "prohibitive . . . exclusivity of property rights may . . . reduce rather than increase the efficiency of resource use." Id.
[FN47]. The condition of perfect knowledge is thus an aspect of the condition of no transaction costs, but the two are usefully stated separately.
[FN48]. If bargains are unenforceable, markets are highly unlikely to form. See R. Posner, supra note 33, at 65-67 (economic rules of contract law). See also Demsetz, The Private Production of Public Goods, 13 J. L. & Econ. 293, 306 (1970) (when nonpurchasers cannot be excluded from using a public good at a reasonable cost, a system of private production "does not seem to be practical"). This aspect of transaction costs becomes important for the discussion of the Betamax case, infra notes 289-322 and accompanying text.
[FN49]. If transaction costs were totally absent, all costs and benefits would necessarily be internalized, and value-maximizing transfers would always take place. See generally Coase, supra note 40; see also Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 38, at 1094-95 & n.12. However, transaction costs are inevitable in the real world of economics, and the nature and impact of those transaction costs may be crucial to a determination of legal rights. See id. at 1096.
[FN50]. Id. at 1095. Relative as well as absolute levels of transaction costs can be important to market evaluations, as can the issue of who bears those costs. If nonparticipating third parties (e.g., taxpayers) bear the transaction costs, that will insulate the bargaining parties from the impact of those costs.
[FN51]. E.g., Truth in Lending Act, 15 U.S.C.A. § § 1601-1667e (West 1974 & Supp.1982); Fair Packaging and Labeling Act, 15 U.S.C. § § 1451-61 (1976).
[FN52]. See Virginia State Bd. of Pharmacy v. Virginia Citizens Consumer Council, Inc., 425 U.S. 748, 770 (1976).
[FN53]. See, e.g., R. Posner, supra note 33, at 212-13.
[FN54]. Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 38, at 1097 (footnote omitted) (referring to the perfect market result as Pareto optimal). The authors define Pareto optimality as "the set of entitlements which would lead to that allocation of resources which could not be improved in the sense that a further change would not so improve the condition of those who gained by it that they could compensate those who lost from it and still be better off than before." Id. at 1094.
[FN55]. See, e.g., R. Posner, supra note 33, at 122, 125. However, both the comparative negligence doctrine and the contributory negligence doctrine inadequately resolve the problem of how to set up incentives when the plaintiff is also negligent. Id. at 123-24. Perhaps the best introduction to the economic analysis of accident law is G. Calabresi, The Costs of Accidents (1970), which ranges far beyond conventional negligence law. See Calabresi's analyses of incentives and market deterrence, id. at 68-94.
[FN56]. Costs must be discounted by the probability of their occurrence. See R. Posner, supra note 33, at 122-23.
[FN57]. See United States v. Carroll Towing Co., 159 F.2d 169, 173 (2d Cir.1947). See generally R. Posner, supra note 33, at 119-59.
[FN58]. Whether the prevailing negligence/contributory negligence pattern in fact provides desirable incentives is of course a matter of much debate. See, e.g., R. Posner, supra note 33, at 122-24; note 55.
[FN59]. See Michelman, supra note 38, at 1180 (discussing "the inability of outside observers to appraise . . . efficiency of proposed social measures"). Cf. Hayek, The Use of Knowledge in Society, 35 Am.Econ.Rev. 519, 524-25 (1945) (arguing that decentralized decisionmaking can often utilize knowledge better than can central planning). See also Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 38, at 1108, 1115-24 (discussing the "likelihood of error" in assessing costs and benefits under various liability rules); id. at 1125 ("liability rules represent only an approximation of the value of the object to the original owner").
[FN60]. While the focus of this fair use discussion is necessarily on judicial rules of decision, other institutions can also perform the balancing function, and the nature of the institution may affect the appropriate rules or principles to be applied. See Michelman, supra note 38, at 1245-57.
[FN61]. See Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 38, at 1124-27 (discussing criminal sanctions).
[FN62]. U.S. Const. art. I, § 8, cl. 8.
[FN63]. The Supreme Court has accepted this premise in several contexts. See, e.g., Mazer v. Stein, 347 U.S. 201, 219 (1954): The economic philosophy behind the clause empowering Congress to grant patents and copyrights is the conviction that encouragement of individual effort by personal gain is the best way to advance public welfare through the talents of authors and inventors in "Science and useful Arts." Sacrificial days devoted to such creative activities deserve rewards commensurate with the services rendered. United States v. Paramount Pictures, Inc., 334 U.S. 131, 158 (1948): The copyright law, like the patent statutes, makes reward to the owner a secondary consideration. In Fox Film Corp. v. Doyal, 286 U.S. 123, 127, Chief Justice Hughes spoke as follows respecting the copyright monopoly granted by Congress, "The sole interest of the United States and the primary object in conferring the monopoly lie in the general benefits derived by the public from the labors of authors." It is said that reward to the author or artist serves to induce release to the public of the products of his creative genius. The role of copyright law in the maintenance of economic incentives has been a matter of significant debate. See, e.g., Breyer, Copyright: A Rejoinder, 20 U.C.L.A.L.Rev. 75 (1972); Breyer, The Uneasy Case for Copyright: A Study of Copyright in Books, Photocopies, and Computer Programs, 84 Harv.L.Rev. 281, 291-323 (1970) [hereinafter cited as Breyer, The Uneasy Case for Copyright]; Hurt & Schuchman, The Economic Rationale of Copyright, 56 Am.Econ.Rev. 421 (1966) (1965 Papers & Proceedings of Am. Econ. Ass'n); Plant, The Economic Aspects of Copyright in Books, 1 Economica 167 (new series 1934); Tyerman, The Economic Rationale for Copyright Protection for Published Books: A Reply to Professor Breyer, 18 U.C.L.A.L.Rev. 1100 (1971). There is also debate about the extent to which the copyright and patent laws serve purposes other than providing incentives. For example, barring potential users from copying encourages them to do their own work. See Gorman, Copyright Protection for the Collection and Representation of Facts, 76 Harv.L.Rev. 1569, 1599 (1963). Intellectual property laws can help structure production to increase the output from resources used for technological innovation. See Kitch, The Nature and Function of the Patent System, 20 J.L. & Econ. 265 (1977). Copyright may also function to protect the author's own interests in, e.g., the integrity of his work. See Breyer, The Uneasy Case for Copyright, supra, at 284-91; Comment, An Author's Artistic Reputation Under the Copyright Act of 1976, 92 Harv.L.Rev. 1490, 1491 (1979). Nevertheless, it generally is agreed that American law gives copyright and patent protection to the producers of intangible products primarily because of the legislative judgment that such systems are necessary if producers of intellectual property are to receive a large enough monetary return for their labors and investments to insure continued production. See Zacchini v. Scripps-Howard Broadcasting Co., 433 U.S. 562, 576 (1977).
[FN64]. Cf. Liebowitz, Copyright and Photocopying: Alternative Institutional Arrangements 3-5 (Feb. 1981) (unpublished manuscript, on file at Columbia Law Review). How the production of public goods should be organized has been the subject of much economic debate. See, e.g., Demsetz, supra note 48 (arguing that under certain circumstances private producers can produce public goods efficiently).
[FN65]. See, e.g., E. Mansfield, Principles of Microeconomics 70 (1974); D. Orr, supra note 38, at 285-311. "A common, collective, or public good is here defined as any good such that, if any person Xi in a group X1, . . . , Xi . . . , Xn consumes it, it cannot feasibly be withheld from others in the group." M. Olson, The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups 14 (1971). Although Olson focuses on this characteristic, he notes that another element in the "traditional understanding of public goods" is "'jointness of supply.' A good has 'jointness' if making it available to one individual means that it can be easily or freely supplied to others as well." Id. at 14 n.21. Professor Demsetz distinguishes between the public good concept . . . which states that it is possible at no cost for additional persons to enjoy the same unit of a public good, and a different concept, that might be identified as a collective good, which imposes the stronger condition that it is impossible to exclude nonpurchasers from consuming the good. Demsetz, supra note 48, at 295. Under this view, national defense, which is the example used in text, see text accompanying notes 66-68, "might be termed an 'approximate collective good."' Demsetz, supra note 48, at 295.
[FN66]. See, e.g., E. Mansfield, supra note 65, at 70, 74-75. See also Markovitz, supra note 33.
[FN67]. See supra note 65.
[FN68]. See, e.g., sources cited supra note 65.
[FN69]. See, e.g., sources cited supra notes 63-65.
[FN70]. Cf. Final Report of the National Commission on New Technological Uses of Copyrighted Works [CONTU] 10 (1978) (discussing computer programs): [I]f the cost of duplicating information is small, then it is simple for a less than scrupulous person to duplicate it. This means that legal as well as physical protection is a necessary incentive if such information is to be created and disseminated. This principle is the underlying principle of copyright . . . . See also Liebowitz, supra note 64, at 4-5. Prior to the 1976 Copyright Act, protection of unpublished literary work was left primarily to state law. This so-called "common law" copyright has been argued to have been essentially a right of privacy, see Warren & Brandeis, The Right To Privacy, 4 Harv.L.Rev. 193, 198-213 (1890), and bears some similarity to state trade secret protection for undisclosed discoveries and inventions. Secret manuscripts are not "public goods"; physical control is sufficient to exclude the unwelcome user. Common law copyright for expression that is fixed in a tangible medium was abolished by 17 U.S.C. § 301 (1976). See House Report, supra note 10, at 129-33, reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News at 5745-49.
[FN71]. See Tyerman, supra note 63, at 1117 (exploring the dangers of relying on government subsidies).
[FN72]. See 17 U.S.C. § 106 (1976) (exclusive rights in copyrighted works); sources cited supra notes 63-65.
[FN73]. Demsetz argues that if nonpurchasers can be excluded efficiency is potentially attainable in a market for public goods. See generally Demsetz, supra note 48.
[FN74]. Generally speaking, the notice on copies must show that copyright is claimed by including three elements: "(c)" (or "copyright" or "copr."), the year of first publication, and the name of the copyright owner. 17 U.S.C. § 401 (Supp. IV 1980). Under some circumstances omitted or defective notice may be forgiven. Id. § § 405-06 (Supp. IV 1980). Note that some uses (e.g., private reading and performance) are not within the scope of the copyright owner's exclusive rights.
[FN75]. Id. § 408 (1976). Like the notice requirement, see supra note 74, the copyright registration requirement is not absolute. See id. Registration is, however, a prerequisite to bringing most infringement actions, id. § 411,and to certain remedies for infringement, id. § 412.
[FN76]. Id. § 506.
[FN77]. See, e.g., id. § 504(c) (1976) (statutory damages); id. § 501 (prima facie proof of infringement, standing); id. § § 502-505 (injunctive relief, impoundment, damages, attorneys' fees). Copyright plaintiffs may find it easier to obtain fee awards than defendants. A. Latman & R. Gorman, supra note 19, at 538.
[FN78]. Note, however, that the copyright law also uses compulsory licensing for some specified classes of works and uses. See, e.g., 17 U.S.C. § 111(c)- (d) (1976) (cable television retransmission of copyrighted material); id. § 115 (phonorecords of nondramatic musical works); id. § 116 ('jukebox' performances).
[FN79]. See supra text accompanying notes 59-61.
[FN80]. See generally Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 38, at 1125-27 (discussing criminal sanctions for intentional market bypass). Compare the discussion of intentional torts, supra notes 59-61 and accompanying text.
[FN81]. As will be seen, the focus is on whether granting fair use to an individual transaction would further the goals of the copyright scheme more than would imposing liability. See generally infra text accompanying notes 92- 124. The transactional, case-by-case approach recommended herein does not require identification of any "optimal" level of overall production. Whether excluding nonpurchasers can allow a market in public goods to achieve optimality is itself a matter of debate. Compare Demsetz, supra note 48 (efficiency achievable if nonpurchasers can be excluded from use), with, e.g., Perlman & Rhinelander, Williams & Wilkins Co. v. United States: Photocopying, Copyright, and the Judicial Process, 1975 Sup.Ct.Rev. 355, 373-79 (criticizing economic analyses of copyright and fair use). It appears that the copyright law treats the outcome of the ordinary copyright transaction as normatively equivalent to an "optimal" result. This Article seeks to identify what distinguishes an ordinary transactional setting from these settings in which the courts are unwilling to trust markets.
[FN82]. Of course, all of the interests are part of society's interests. Compare Michelman, supra note 38, at 1194 (analyzing the nature of balancing tests). At issue also is the public interest is the public interest in preserving incentives.
[FN83]. See infra notes 84 & 131.
[FN84]. Studies prepared for the Subcomm. on Patents, Trademarks and Copyrights of the Senate Comm. on the Judiciary, 86th Cong., 1st Sess., The Compulsory License Provisions of the U.S. Copyright Law (Study No. 5) 11 (Comm. Print 1960) (H. Henn). It has been suggested that some of the fears of monopoly may have been unwarranted. See id. at 3 n.20, 11 n.44. The provisions governing this compulsory license appeared at § 1(e) of the Copyright Act of 1909, 35 Stat. 1075 (codified and reenacted 1947, amended 1976), and appear at § 115 of the 1976 Act. 17 U.S.C. § 115 (1976). The provisions are not triggered until the copyright owner has himself taken some action to avail himself of the possibility of making mechanical recordings. Compulsory licenses are a likely compromise when new rights are granted. See, e.g., Second Supplementary Report of the Register of Copyrights of the General Revision of U.S. Copyright Law: 1975 Revision Bill (Draft, October-December 1975) at VII 18-20 (fears expressed that extending copyright to typefaces would allow a "few big manufacturers . . . to enforce tying arrangements between their machines and fonts" or "might lead to suits to enjoin publication of printed matter;" "mandatory licensing" discussed as a possible solution). See also 17 U.S.C. § 111 (1976) (cable television retransmission of copyrighted material).
[FN85]. This Article does not purport to present an exhaustive list of the reasons why a court might refuse to enforce a copyright owner's market right. It is submitted, however, that in all cases where protected subject matter has been appropriated, the courts should give consideration to whether there is a good reason--founded in economics or otherwise--to depart from the market.
[FN86]. See infra notes 149-98 and accompanying text.
[FN87]. This Article will be using economics to identify certain market defects that are particularly salient, and that appear to cause courts to doubt the appropriateness of enforcing a copyright owner's market right.
[FN88]. These first two considerations are closely analogous to those at work in the negligence model discussed supra in text accompanying notes 55-58
[FN89]. Note, Parody and Copyright Infringement, 56 Colum.L.Rev. 585, 595 (1956) ("Fair use . . . can be defined as a use which will not seriously discourage progress by artists or as a use whose social value greatly outweighs any detriment to the artist whose work is borrowed.") (footnote omitted). See also Marsh, Betamax and Fair Use: A Shotgun Marriage, 21 Santa Clara L.Rev. 49, 58 (1981).
[FN90]. See supra note 59.
[FN91]. See infra notes 149-98 and accompanying text.
[FN92]. See supra notes 37-38 and accompanying text. The second part of the test inquires into the minimum price plaintiff would accept in a hypothetical market to recompense him for the injury caused by the defendant's specific use. The broader issue of real-world injury to the market as a whole is the subject of the third part of the test. See infra notes 115-17 and accompanying text.
[FN93]. See R. Posner, supra note 33, at 10-12 (voluntary transactions result in a net increase in value).
[FN94]. See infra notes 163-75 and accompanying text.
[FN95]. See generally Meeropol v. Nizer, 560 F.2d 1061, 1069-71 (2d Cir.1977) (discussing purpose and necessity of use), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1013 (1978); Williams & Wilkins Co. v. United States, 487 F.2d 1345 (Ct.Cl. 1973) (value of medical research) (discussed supra notes 249-88 and accompanying text), aff'd by an equally divided Court, 420 U.S. 376 (1975) (per curiam); Elsmere Music, Inc. v. NBC, 482 F.Supp. 741, 745-47 (S.D.N.Y.) (discussing valid parody as fair use), aff'd, 623 F.2d 252 (2d Cir.1980); Time, Inc. v. Bernard Geis Assocs., 293 F.Supp. 130, 145-46 (S.D.N.Y. 1968) (finding "a public interest in having the fullest information available on the murder of President Kennedy"). Intuitive estimates may often be required because of overall imperfections in the market structure, see infra note 96, though reference to prices may provide useful constraints for this intuition.
[FN96]. The 1976 Copyright Act reflects both these elements in its damages provision: "The copyright owner is entitled to recover the actual damages suffered by him or her as a result of the infringement, and any profits of the infringer that are attributable to the infringement and are not taken into account in computing the actual damages." 17 U.S.C. § 504(b) (1976). See also cases cited supra note 95. Note, however, that insofar as the overall market remains imperfect, actual prices and profits might not accurately reflect social desirability, even if that desirability is measured solely in economic terms. See E. Mansfield, supra note 65, at 334 (discussing "theory of the second best"). Therefore, although such criteria can provide a court with usefully objective guides for its inquiry into public interest, they might not be determinative.
[FN97]. See, e.g., Triangle Publications, Inc. v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers, Inc., 626 F.2d 1171, 1177-78 (5th Cir.1980); Williams & Wilkins Co. v. United States, 487 F.2d 1345, 1357-59, 1362-63 (Ct.Cl. 1973), aff'd by an equally divided Court, 420 U.S. 376 (1975) (per curiam); Time, Inc. v. Bernard Geis Assocs., 293 F.Supp. 130, 146 (S.D.N.Y. 1968). See also 17 U.S.C. § 107 (1976) ("In determining whether the use made of a work in any particular case is a fair use the factors to be considered shall include-- . . . (4) the effect of the use upon the potential market for or value of the copyrighted work."). Nimmer calls market effect the "central fair use factor." 3 M. Nimmer, Nimmer on Copyright § 13.05[A][4], at 13-64 (1982) (footnote omitted).
[FN98]. See R. Posner, supra note 33, at 3-12.
[FN99]. W. Prosser, Handbook of the Law of Torts § 18, at 103 (4th ed. 1971) (footnote omitted).
[FN100]. Id. at 103.
[FN101]. Id.
[FN102]. If one would consent to a situation, it is arguably "fair" to impose that situation when obtaining actual consent is costly or impossible. As a member of society, the copyright owner shares in the cost savings effected by eliminating the need for actual consent in certain situations. See, e.g., Michelman, supra note 38, at 1176-81 ("to insist on full compensation to every interest which is disproportionately burdened by a social measure dictated by efficiency would be to call a halt to the collective pursuit of efficiency"). Moreover, since an additional branch of the fair use test protects against substantial injury, see infra notes 104-24 and accompanying text, the copyright owner has some protection against the possibility that he will be harmed more than benefited in the long run. Consider the relation between procedure, fairness, and substantive result discussed in J. Rawls, A Theory of Justice (1971), particularly in chapters 1- 3 (considering what principles persons under certain hypothetical conditions would consent to adopt). For an excellent discussion of the many meanings that "consent" can take in political analysis, see Pitkin, Obligation and Consent- 1, 59 Am.Pol.Sci.Rev. 990 (1965), and Pitkin, Obligation and Consent-II, 60 Am.Pol.Sci.Rev. 39 (1966). "Consent" has had a role in fair use commentary. See, e.g., Studies Prepared for the Subcomm. on Patents, Trademarks and Copyrights of the Senate Comm. on the Judiciary, Fair Use of Copyrighted Works 15, 86th Cong., 2d Sess., (Study No. 14) (Comm. Print 1960) [hereinafter cited as Latman Study].
[FN103]. The impact on aggregate value caused by the immediate transfer is only part of the relevant inquiry.
[FN104]. See also Comment, Photocopying and Fair Use: An Examination of the Economic Factor in Fair Use, 26 Emory L.J. 849, 865-71 (1977).
[FN105]. In appropriate cases, awarding the plaintiff a damage remedy may also allow the user continued access to the work. See infra notes 125-34 and accompanying text.
[FN106]. Damage by substitution is of course the damage to which the fair use criteria are most sensitive. See, e.g., M. Nimmer, supra note 97, § 13.05 [B], at 13-65 to 13-72.
[FN107]. This hurdle serves not only to protect the individual copyright owner from substantial loss but to protect society as a whole from erosion of the copyright system. Compare the function of the "just compensation" guarantee as discussed in Michelman, supra note 38.
[FN108]. See supra notes 55-58 and accompanying text.
[FN109]. Id.
[FN110]. Broader economic views of accident law might, however, take a different view. See G. Calabresi, supra note 55, at 39-67 (exploring modes of spreading heavy losses).
[FN111]. See Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 38, at 1106-10.
[FN112]. Where Congress has elected to give copyright owners a property right in the first instance, doubts should be resolved in the owner's favor.
[FN113]. Although the dominant view is clearly that authors receive their property right for a larger social purpose, Congress has shown special solicitude for the welfare of individual authors, even as opposed to publishers and other potential owners of copyright. See 17 U.S.C. § § 203, 304(c) (1976) (termination rights); House Report, supra note 10, at 140, reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News at 5756 ("the author, who is the fundamental beneficiary of copyright under the Constitution," is given the right to terminate grants that he may have made to publishers and other assignees; made-for-hire works not terminable).
[FN114]. See also Michelman, supra note 38, at 1177-80, 1208-24 (discussing demoralization costs).
[FN115]. See also M. Nimmer, supra note 97, § 13.05[A][4], at 13-64 to 13- 65 (effect of the use upon the [plaintiff's] potential market "poses the issue of whether unrestricted and widespread conduct of the sort engaged in by the defendant . . . would result in a substantially adverse impact on the potential market for or value of the plaintiff's work"); id. § 13.05[E][4][c], at 13-84.
[FN116]. Senate Report, supra note 26, at 65.
[FN117]. See supra note 115.
[FN118]. Cf. Williams & Wilkins Co. v. United States, 487 F.2d 1345, 1359 (Ct.Cl. 1973) (finding, interalia, large-scale library photocopying was not proven to be detrimental to the circulation and future commercial value of plaintiff's medical journals), aff'd by an equally divided Court, 420 U.S. 376 (1975) (per curiam); Time, Inc. v. Bernard Geis Assocs., 293 F.Supp. 130, 146 (S.D.N.Y. 1968) (finding no significant potential for future injury to the value of the Zapruder films of the Kennedy assassination caused by the unlicensed publication of sketches of the key frames in a book advancing a novel theory about the assassination); M. Nimmer, supra note 97, § 13.05[A][4], at 13-65 (courts should look at conduct regardless of "whether in fact engaged in by defendant or others"); id. § 13.05[E][4][c], at 13-84 ("all potential defendants").
[FN119]. Discussion about what market structure would follow from a judgment of liability will necessarily involve a judgment of probabilities.
[FN120]. Photocopying was at issue in Williams & Wilkins Co. v. United States, 487 F.2d 1345 (Ct.Cl. 1973), aff'd by an equally divided Court, 420 U.S. 376 (1975) (per curiam), discussed infra text accompanying notes 249-88. Williams & Wilkins Co. has evoked substantial scholarly comment. See, e.g., M. Nimmer, supra note 97, § 13.05[E][4][c]-[e], at 13-82 to 13-92; Perlman & Rhinelander, supra note 81.
[FN121]. Home videotaping of on-the-air television programs is of course the issue in the Betamax case, Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 480 F.Supp. 429, 435 (C.D.Cal. 1979), rev'd in part and remanded, 659 F.2d 963 (9th Cir.1981), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687), discussed infra text accompanying notes 289-322. The district court decision in the case has been extensively discussed. See, e.g., Note, Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp.: "Fair Use" Looks Different on Videotape, 66 Va.L.Rev. 1005 (1980); Note, The Betamax Case: Accommodating Public Access and Economic Incentive in Copyright Law, 31 Stan.L.Rev. 243 (1979) [hereinafter cited as Stanford Note].
[FN122]. Compare the view of custom presented herein with Rosenfield, Customary Use as "Fair Use" in Copyright Law, 25 Buff.L.Rev. 119 (1975).
[FN123]. See, e.g., the discussion of the form and function of clearinghouses in Hampton, Clearing House as Optimum Solution to Copyright Problems Affecting Communication of Educational and Scientific Information, in Reprography and Copyright Law 189 (L. Hattery & G. Bush eds. 1964).
[FN124]. Rosenfield argues that in the context of fair use, a copyright owner should be prevented "from seeking a greater monopoly than he would have had with the earlier systems of reproducing copies." Rosenfield, supra note 122, at 122. Rosenfield also argues that the custom of nonpayment, see infra notes 224-33 and accompanying text, is an independent justification for fair use, because, inter alia, "the law loses credibility with the public" if "a teacher, researcher or scholar may lawfully copy for his private, non-profit use only under conditions of maximum inefficiency in the use of technology, time and resources." Id. at 136 (footnote omitted) (discussing photocopying). There is some merit in Rosenfield's credibility argument. United States Representative Stanford Parris of Virginia, for one, has termed the Ninth Circuit's Betamax decision as "the latest example of idiocy in the federal judiciary," Fortune, Feb. 1982, at 126, and humorists have poked considerable fun at the image of persons being arrested in their homes for misusing their living-room videorecorders. However, arguments premised on custom and expectation can easily be drawn too far. Among other things, the circumstances that gave rise to the custom can be changed; the ridicule that the Betamax result has occasionally drawn in the popular press might have been avoided if the Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals had focused on whether the courts could so change the economic arrangements that enforcement would not necessitate impractical court actions against each individual user. Of course, this might be implicit in the posture of the case. The only individual home user who was named as a defendant in the Betamax was not a real target of that litigation; rather he was "a client of plaintiffs' law firm" who "consented to being a defendant," and against whom plaintiffs had "waived any claim for damages or costs." Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 480 F.Supp. 429, 437 (C.D.Cal. 1979), rev'd in part and remanded, 659 F.2d 963 (9th Cir.1981), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687). Nevertheless, the popular perception of the case was probably quite influenced by the Ninth Circuit's refusal to make consideration of relief (i.e., whether changes in the technology or market structure would occur to make user fees easy to collect in a nonintrusive manner) part of its consideration of liability. See generally the discussion of the Betamax case infra text accompanying notes 289-322.
[FN125]. Calabresi and Melamed, in their seminal article, Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral, supra note 38, made it clear that the law has many choices, not only as to who should possess an entitlement, but also as to how such an entitlement should be protected. The modes of protection include "property rules" such as injunctive remedies, and "liability rules" such as damage remedies. When the owner's entitlement is protected by property rules, he may sell his right at a price of his choosing, or may refuse to sell. But when his entitlement is protected by liability rules, the owner may not prevent an involuntary transfer; rather he will be permitted to collect a court determined price (i.e., damages) for the value of the rights he has lost. Calabresi and Melamed write: An entitlement is protected by a property rule to the extent that someone who wishes to remove the entitlement from its holder must buy it from him in a voluntary transaction in which the value of the entitlement is agreed upon by the seller. . . . [O]nce the original entitlement is decided upon, the state does not try to decide its value. . . . Whenever someone may destroy the initial entitlement if he is willing to pay an objectively determined value for it, an entitlement is protected by a liability rule. Id. at 1092 (footnote omitted). The grant of monetary relief in place of an injunction for copyright infringement would be an example of a liability rule. Whether the copyright law permits the substitution of a liability rule for a property rule is a matter of debate. See, e.g., Nimmer, copyright liability for Audio Home Recording: Dispelling the Betamax Myth, 68 Va.L.Rev. 1505, 1530- 31 (1982) (arguing in favor of court-imposed royalty).
[FN126]. Although a bargain can often be struck in which enjoined parties pay those holding the injunction to let them proceed, market failure may make this impossible in a given case. See Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 38, at 1118-19.
[FN127]. Such alternatives have been widely discussed. See, e.g., M. Nimmer, supra note 97, § 13.05[E], at 13-91 to 13-92; Timberg, A Modernized Fair Use Code for the Electronic as Well as the Gutenberg Age, 75 NW.U.L.Rev. 193, 233-44 (1980); Stanford Note, supra note 121, at 257-62.
[FN128]. See supra notes 125-27.
[FN129]. The Williams & Wilkins court questioned the judiciary's abilities and authority in this regard. See infra notes 271 & 273.
[FN130]. See sources cited supra note 59.
[FN131]. Compulsory licenses appear at, e.g., 17 U.S.C. § § 111(d) (Supp. IV 1980) (cable television), id. § 115 (phonorecords), id. § 116 (jukeboxes). A Copyright Royalty Tribunal has been created, inter alia, to review and adjust statutory royalty rates. Id. § 801. The courts' role in reviewing such rates is limited. Id. § 810 (judicial review). An exception to this general approach appears in the 1976 Copyright Act in regard to innocent infringements that may be traced to the copyright holder's omission of a notice of copyright. The omission of notice may itself cause market failure, for a potential user would not know copyright is claimed. See supra text accompanying note 74. Congress has given the courts in that context the power to impose a reasonable license fee as a condition to continued use of the copyrighted materials. Id. § 405(b).
[FN132]. See, e.g., Staff of Senate Comm. on the Judiciary, 86th Cong., 1st Sess., Copyright Law Revision Studies pts. 5-6 (Comm. Print 1960). See also House Report, supra note 10, at 175-78 (compulsory licensing provisions for cable television).
[FN133]. See A. Latman & R. Gorman, supra note 19, at 455-58 (discussion of the protracted antitrust litigation, brought by the government and CBS against the licensing practices of ASCAP and BMI). The result of these judicial proceedings has been a series of consent decrees. Id.
[FN134]. The 1909 Copyright Act survived with only piecemeal revisions until 1976. A draft bill for the comprehensive revision that became the 1976 Act was first introduced in both houses in 1964. See House Report, supra note 10, at 47-50. However, it should be noted that Congress may act more quickly in response to the Betamax controversy; bills have been submitted and hearings have been held. See, e.g., 24 Pat. Trademark & Copyright J. (BNA) 577-78 (Oct. 7, 1982).
[FN135]. There is a substantial disagreement among the scholars about the nature and allocation of the burden of proving injury in fair use litigation. See, e.g., M. Nimmer, supra note 97, § 13.05[E][4][c], at 13-82 to 13-86; Comment, supra note 104, at 869-84. The courts also disagree about the character of this burden. In Williams & Wilkins for instance, the court wrote: To us it is very important that plaintiff has failed to prove its assumption of economic detriment, in the past or potentially for the future. One of the factors always considered with respect to "fair use," . . . is the effect of the use on the owner's potential market for the work. This record simply does not show a serious adverse impact, either on plaintiff or on medical publishers generally, from the photocopying practices of the type of NIH [National Institutes of Health] and NLM [National Library of Medicine]. In the face of this record, we cannot mechanically assume such an effect, or hold that the amount of photoduplication proved here "must" lead to financial or economic harm. This is a matter of proof and plaintiff has not transformed its hypothetical assumption, by evidence, into a proven fact. Williams & Wilkins Co. v. United States, 487 F.2d 1345, 1359 (Ct.Cl. 1973), aff'd by an equally divided Court, 420 U.S. 376 (1975) (per curiam). Similarly, the district court in the Betamax case noted that "plaintiffs ask the court to find harm." Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 480 F.Supp. 429, 451 (C.D.Cal. 1979), rev'd in part and remanded, 659 F.2d 963 (9th Cir.1981), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687). By contrast, the Ninth Circuit rejected this approach to allocating the burden: "[Proof of actual damages] is simply too great a burden to impose on copyright plaintiffs." Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 659 F.2d 963, 974 (9th Cir.1981), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687). See also Encyclopedia Britannica Educational Corp. v. Crooks, 447 F.Supp. 243, 251 (W.D.N.Y. 1978) ("[T]he burden of establishing fair use is on the defendant and . . . the plaintiff in a copyright case is presumed to suffer irreparable injury.").
[FN136]. The 1965 copyright revision bill had a fair use section that provided, in its entirety, that "the fair use of a copyrighted work is not an infringement of copyright." Although this early version of § 107 more than quadrupled in length on its way to enactment in 1976, the basic characterization did not change. 17 U.S.C. § 107 (Supp. IV 1980). The Register of Copyrights said about the early § 107: The author-publisher interests have suggested that fair use should be treated as a defense, with the statute placing the burden of proof on the user. The educational group has urged just the opposite, that the statute should provide that any nonprofit use for educational purposes is presumed to be a fair use, with the copyright owner having the burden of proving otherwise. We believe it would be undesirable to adopt a special rule placing the burden of proof on one side or the other. When the facts as to what use was made of the work have been presented, the issue as to whether it is a "fair use" is a question of law. Statutory presumptions or burden-of-proof provisions could work a radical change in the meaning and effect of the doctrine of fair use. The intention of section 107 is to give statutory affirmation to the present judicial doctrine, not to change it. Register of Copyrights, 89th Cong., 1st Sess., Supplementary Report of the Register of Copyrights on the General Revision of the U.S. Copyright Law: 1965 Revision Bill 28 (Comm. Print 1965).
[FN137]. See supra notes 62-87 and accompanying text.
[FN138]. See Nimmer, supra note 9, at 1053.
[FN139]. Section 504(c) of 17 U.S.C. (Supp. IV 1980) provides plaintiffs the option of electing statutory damages in lieu of proving actual damages in an infringement action. The election of statutory damages may be made at any time before judgment is entered. Id. By electing statutory damages, the copyright owner may recover between $250 and $10,000 for any one infringement by any one infringer, the sum to be determined by the court. Id. § 504(c)(1). Greater or lesser amounts may be awarded in certain circumstances. Id. § 501(c)(2). According to Nimmer, this statutory damage option is made available because "[i]t is inherently difficult in copyright infringement actions for a plaintiff to prove actual damages as against a given defendant." Nimmer, supra note 9, at 1053.
[FN140]. See Nimmer, supra note 9.
[FN141]. Since defendant is a member of society, ordinarily his use will have some social value. This will not always be true, however. One case in which the defendant's use had no apparent social value is Amana Refrigeration, Inc. v. Consumers Union, Inc. 431 F.Supp. 324 (N.D. Iowa 1977). Amana, in an effort to counteract a critical Consumer Reports appraisal of its microwave ovens, had published a brochure featuring a full paragraph from an earlier, more favorable, Consumer Reports evaluation. Consumers Union requested that Amana withdraw the brochure and Amana responded by bringing an unfair trade practice claim. Consumers Union defended on the ground that the brochure was deceptive, and counterclaimed that Amana had violated the Consumer Reports copyright. Finding that in publishing the brochure Amana "was attempting to convey the impression that [Consumers Union] approved of [Amana's] microwave oven as of 1973 when the exact opposite was true," id. at 326, the court dismissed Amana's defense of fair use to the counterclaim and issued in injunction barring any further distribution of the brochure. Id. at 327.
[FN142]. Even when defendant's use has some social value, that value must be significant enough to outweigh plaintiff's injury. See supra notes 92-103 and accompanying text.
[FN143]. See infra note 221 (relation between types of injury and fair use).
[FN144]. A particular party's access to proof on an issue is, of course, often advanced as a reason for putting the burden as to that issue on him. See, e.g., Comment, supra note 104, at 869.
[FN145]. See, e.g., Meeropol v. Nizer, 417 F.Supp. 1201, 1213 (S.D.N.Y. 1976), rev'd on other grounds, 560 F.2d 1061 (2d Cir.1977), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1013 (1978).
[FN146]. See, e.g., Rosemont Enters., Inc. v. Random House, Inc., 366 F.2d 303, 304, 306-07 (2d Cir.1966), cert. denied, 385 U.S. 1009 (1967). See also Cohen, Fair Use in the Law of Copyright, 6 ASCAP Copyright L. Symp. 43, 45-48 (1955).
[FN147]. See Cohen, supra note 146; Comment, supra note 104, at 871-75. Section 107 provides that fair use "is not an infringement of copyright." 17 U.S.C. § 107 (Supp. IV 1980). See supra note 136.
[FN148]. In a suit for unintentional torts, the plaintiff has to show that defendant's acts were wrongful and that he (plaintiff) was injured. It can be argued that fair use acts as a repository for these elements of a plaintiff's cause of action when market failure calls into question whether the user justifiably bypassed the market and whether injury occurred. See supra text accompanying notes 55-61. See also Comment, supra note 104, at 869, which argues that harm from photocopying is improbable and courts should therefore require plaintiffs to prove economic injury in the photocopying context.
[FN149]. See supra text accompanying notes 89-91.
[FN150]. Senate Report, supra note 26, at 64.
[FN151]. Id. In a given case, the out-of-print status of a work can trigger market failure, yet fair use would be inappropriate because allowing uncompensated use would injure the copyright owner's future market for a second printing. Recognizing the separability of the two issues to which out-of-print status can be relevant--the issue of market failure--can clarify some of the current ambiguity over the matter. Compare Senate Report, supra note 26, at 64, with, e.g., Mceropol v. Nizer, 560 F.2d 1061, 1070 (2d Cir.1977) ("The fact that the Rosenberg letters have been out of print for 20 years does not necessarily mean they have no future market which can be injured."), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1013 (1978).
[FN152]. See Triangle Publications, Inc. v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers, Inc., 626 F.2d 1171, 1176 n.14 (5th Cir.1980) ("If the copyrighted work is out of print and cannot be purchased, a use may be more likely to prevail on a fair use defense.") (emphasis added) (citing Senate Report, supra note 26, at 64 ("Availability of the work")).
[FN153]. See House Report, supra note 10, at 68-69.
[FN154]. Id. at 69.
[FN155]. Of course, if an outside party like the government bears the transaction costs, the parties will not be prevented from achieving their bargain, but an inordinate amount of transaction costs might then be imposed on society. While shifting the burden of transaction costs may be appropriate in some circumstances, the focus here instead should be on reducing these costs.
[FN156]. See, e.g., Williams & Wilkins Co. v. United States, 487 F.2d 1345, 1355 (Ct.Cl. 1973) ("personal, individual focus" of the photocopy), aff'd by an equally divided Court, 420 U.S. 376 (1975) (per curiam). See also Twentieth Century Music Corp. v. Aiken, 422 U.S. 151 (1975) (small commercial establishment using home radio receiver to bring music to customers held not to be "performing" and thus not liable for copyright infringement).
[FN157]. The home use of audio tape recorders has been referred to as "fair use." See remarks of Rep. Kastenmeier quoted in Universal City Studios v. Sony Corp. of America. 480 F.Supp. 429, 446 (C.D.Cal. 1979), rev'd in part and remanded, 659 F.2d 963 (9th Cir.1981), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687).
[FN158]. See, e.g., Breyer, The Uneasy Case for Copyright, supra note 63, at 316-18 ("[S]ome potential users, willing to pay royalties but unwilling to pay the transactions' costs, will not obtain the copyrighted item."). The discussion in text relates to a common point made by lawyer-economists. A market works to transfer resources to their highest-valued resources. R. Posner, supra note 33, at 1-13, 27-31. Professor Coase has argued that when transaction costs are absent, it does not matter where the legal system assigns rights to the resources. Where transactions can be conducted costlessly, resources will gravitate naturally to those willing to pay the most for them, through a series of consensual exchanges. Coase, supra note 40. When transaction costs are high, on the other hand, some economists argue that rights should be assigned so as to promote the allocation of resources to their highest valued use. See R. Posner, supra note 33, at 34-39. Where transaction costs may be quite high in relation to the gain to be anticipated from transfers, fair use operates to make sure that certain uses are placed (without need of purchase) in the hands of those who value them most.
[FN159]. Encyclopaedia Britannica Educational Corp. v. Crooks, 542 F.Supp. 1156, 1177-78 (W.D.N.Y. 1982).
[FN160]. The availability of the copyrighted works was one of the key grounds used by the court to distinguish Williams & Wilkins. Id. at 1177. See also the court's prior opinion in granting a preliminary injunction, 447 F.Supp. 243, 251-52 (W.D.N.Y. 1978).
[FN161]. These cases are discussed infra notes 224-40 and accompanying text. Note that the focus in such cases is on whether a copyright owner is likely to have actual reasons for being willing to allow the use, or on whether he has manifested such a willingness; in such cases, the defendant "can justify himself upon some principle consistent with the entirety of ownership which the author has in his copyright." Reed v. Holliday, 19 F. 325, 327 (W.D.Pa. 1884). Likely consent reflects not just a measure of social welfare but also the fact that the copyright owner will not be injured.
[FN162]. Without fair use, the necessity of obtaining consent might wastefully apply even to those defendants whose activities would have been objected to by no one. The reason for this potential waste is that the availability of injunctive relief and statutory damages provides a motive for objecting, once a use has been made, even to those copyright owners who would have been inclined to consent ab ante. Once an injunction is obtained, the owner controls not merely the use of his own work, but also all aspects of defendant's work that are intertwined with it. See 17 U.S.C. § 502 (1976) (injunctions); id. § 503 (impounding and disposition of infringing articles). A great deal will then be at risk for the defendant, who might be willing to settle at high cost in order to lift the injunction and proceed with his enterprise. Also, the statutory damage provisions will ordinarily give a neglected copyright owner from $250 to $10,000, see id. § 504(c), and there is a potential for costs and attorneys' fees. See id. § 505. Thus, even a copyright owner who would have been willing to consent to a use if his permission were sought before the use commenced might bring suit if the use had begun without that permission. Potential users would be unable to distinguish between those likely-consenting owners who would later object and those who would not. This possibility could in turn compel potential users to expend resources in negotiating for consent even from the willing. To award fair use where a typical copyright owner would be likely to consent breaks this circle. Consider by analogy the hold-out problem that sometimes arises when a builder needs to purchase many individually owned tracts of land in order to accomplish a planned project. The problems caused by strategic hold-out behavior have been cited as justification for granting the government power to condemn property via eminent domain. See Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 38, at 1089. The injunctive and other modes of relief just discussed may give a copyright owner hold-out power over a defendant's work, and this may provide some justification for granting defendants the power to make use of the copyright owner's property via fair use. But see Demsetz, supra note 48, at 300 ("[S]o long as firms are free to compete for the trade of buyers, this [hold out] issue will reduce to a problem of wealth distribution and not to a problem of efficiency.").
[FN163]. See supra notes 32-87 and accompanying text.
[FN164]. See Time Inc. v. Bernard Geis Assocs., 293 F.Supp. 130 (S.D.N.Y. 1968).
[FN165]. For more thorough explanations of externalities, see, e.g., R. Posner, supra note 33, at 48-52; N. Singer, supra note 38, at 107-15; E. Mansfield, supra note 65, at 70-71, 74-75, 336-37.
[FN166]. 17 U.S.C. § 107 (1976).
[FN167]. Id.
[FN168]. See Hansmann, The Role of Nonprofit Enterprise, 89 Yale L.J. 835 (1980).
[FN169]. See WXIA-TV v. Duncan, 8 Med.L.Rptr. 2075, 2078-79 (N.D.Ga. 1982) (need to maintain impartiality may preclude copyright owner from selling films of its news stories to subjects of such stories).
[FN170]. See, e.g., Keep Thomson Governor Comm. v. Citizens for Gallen Comm., 457 F.Supp. 957, 959-60 (D.N.H. 1978) (portion of political opponent's campaign music incorporated into political advertisement); Time, Inc. v. Bernard Geis Assocs., 293 F.Supp. 130, 146 (S.D.N.Y. 1968) (theory concerning Kennedy assassination). Note that in the latter case defendants had "offer[ed] to surrender to [the copyright owner] all profits of [the defendants] from the Book as royalty payment for a license to use the copyrighted Zapruder frames [of the Kennedy assassination], id. at 146, thereby further underlining the nonmonetizable nature of the concerns at stake.
[FN171]. Consider in this regard the solicitude shown by the Court of Claims for medicine and science in Williams & Wilkins, discussed infra text accompanying notes 249-88.
[FN172]. Since a society may hold conflicting values, it may be incapable of weighing the importance of its various goals by any constant measure. See generally G. Calabresi & P. Bobbit, supra note 34.
[FN173]. Several commentators and courts have discussed the possibility that the first amendment may place a limitation on enforcement of the copyright owner's market rights or that fair use may embody some first amendment principles. See, e.g., Keep Thomson Governor Comm. v. Citizens for Gallen Comm., 457 F.Supp. 957, 959-60 (D.N.H. 1978); Denicola, supra note 39. Note that the copyright law itself provides that "[i]n no case does copyright protection extend to any idea," 17 U.S.C. § 102(b) (1976), a principle that operates regardless of injury to the copyright owner. At least one district court has held that the first amendment could defeat an infringement suit. Triangle Publications, Inc. v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers, Inc., 445 F.Supp. 875 (S.D.Fla. 1978), aff'd on grounds of fair use without reaching first amendment issue, 626 F.2d 1171 (5th Cir.1980). More common is the position that, while cases demanding the adoption of an express first amendment limitation on copyright may theoretically or eventually arise, "[c]onflicts between interests protected by the first amendment and the copyright laws thus far have been resolved by application of the fair use doctrine." Wainwright Securities, Inc. v. Wall Street Transcript Corp., 558 F.2d 91, 95 (2d Cir.1977) (citations omitted), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1014 (1978). See generally A. Latman & R. Gorman, supra note 19, at 473-74 (discussing, inter alia, those cases that have rejected first amendment defenses).
[FN174]. See supra note 36.
[FN175]. This may be the nature of Seltzer's concern when he warns the courts against engaging in reallocation of costs. See L. Seltzer, supra note 4, at 38.
[FN176]. 17 U.S.C. § 107 (1976).
[FN177]. "It has been held that an author is entitled to more extensive use of another's copyrighted work in creating a parody than in creating other fictional or dramatic works . . . ." Elsmere Music, Inc. v. NBC, 482 F.Supp. 741, 745 (S.D.N.Y. 1980), aff'd, 623 F.2d 252 (2d Cir.1980) (citations omitted).
[FN178]. In Rosemont Enters., Inc. v. Random House, Inc., 366 F.2d 303, 311 (2d Cir.1966), cert. denied, 385 U.S. 1009 (1967), Howard Hughes, having purchased through the Rosemont corporation the copyright on articles concerning his life, sought to restrain a biographer's use of the articles. "[I]t appears that the fair use defense was upheld in Rosemont at least in part because the court found that the plaintiff there was acting in bad faith seeking to prevent the publication of a legitimate biography of Howard Hughes." Meeropol v. Nizer, 560 F.2d 1061, 1069 (2d Cir.1977) (footnote omitted), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1013 (1978).
[FN179]. See Keep Thomson Governor Comm. v. Citizens for Gallen Comm., 457 F.Supp. 957 (D.N.H. 1978) (fair use granted to political opponent's use of copyrighted material).
[FN180]. In Triangle Publications, Inc. v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers, Inc., 626 F.2d 1171 (5th Cir.1980), the publishers of the Miami Herald had shown old TV Guide covers as part of advertisements comparing TV Guide with the Herald's television supplement. TV Guide's motivation for refusing permission to use these covers would seem to be related not to a desire to exploit those covers' aesthetic qualities, but rather to a desire to prevent consumers from being persuaded by the ads. When TV Guide brought suit, fair use was found.
[FN181]. See cases and statute cited supra notes 176-80.
[FN182]. See, e.g., A. Latman & R. Gorman, supra note 19, at 484-85; M. Nimmer, Comments and Views Submitted to the Copyright Office on Fair Use of Copyrighted Works, appended to Latman Study, supra note 102, at 42, 43. Sheldon Light valuably put this argument into an explicit economic framework. Light, Parody, Burlesque and the Economic Rationale for Copyright, 11 Conn.L.Rev. 615 (1979).
[FN183]. Of course, an injury to a copyright owner arising out of increased consumer knowledge would not be injury relevant to the second or third parts of the test. Copyright law seeks to guard against decreased demand for the copyright owner's product arising out of substitution; when decreased demand arises out of changed consumer preferences, that should be reflected in decreased revenues. See A. Latman & R. Gorman, supra note 19, at 485 (raising a similar issue).
[FN184]. Virginia Pharmacy Bd. v. Virginia Consumer Council, Inc., 425 U.S. 748, 765 (1976).
[FN185]. Economics seeks to satisfy consumer tastes, however they may evolve, and assumes "that man is a rational maximizer of his ends in life." R. Posner, supra note 33, at 3.
[FN186]. Such motives might in an extreme case be termed "bad faith," reflecting on the equitable origins of the fair use doctrine. See Meeropol v. Nizer, 560 F.2d 1061, 1069 (2d Cir.1977), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1013 (1978).
[FN187]. See Roy Export Co. Estab. of Vaduz v. CBS, 503 F.Supp. 1137, 1147 n.6 (S.D.N.Y. 1980), aff'd, 672 F.2d 1095 (2d Cir.1982).
[FN188]. See Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer, Inc. v. Showcase Atlanta Coop. Prods., Inc., 479 F.Supp. 351, 360-61 (N.D.Ga.1979) ("The Court first recognizes that a non-parodic or non-satiric stage version of [plaintiff's work] Gone With the Wind is a protected derivative use of the original works which only the holders of the valid, existing copyrights in such works have a right to exploit. . . . [Defendant's play] 'Scarlett Fever' could harm a potential market for or value of a stage version of Gone With the Wind.").
[FN189]. But see Goldstein, supra note 39, at 1056 ("The infringer is . . . the sole proponent of the generalized interest in access . . . .").
[FN190]. On the allocation of the burden of proof, see supra text accompanying notes 135-148.
[FN191]. It should also be noted, however, that while fair use may be appropriate when copyrights in published works are improperly used for the purpose of manipulating public debate, fair use should not be used to force disclosure of works that the author has heretofore kept secret. The right to privacy that found expression in the "right of first publication" in common-law copyright, see Warren & Brandeis, supra note 70, should still be honored, at least for truly private works such as undisclosed diaries and the like. See Senate Report, supra note 26, at 64 ("The applicability of the fair use doctrine to unpublished works is narrowly limited . . . ."). But see M. Nimmer, supra note 97, § 13.05 n.2, at 13-54.
[FN192]. In New York Times Co. v. Roxbury Data Interface, Inc., 434 F.Supp. 217 (D.N.J. 1977), the court refused, on fair use grounds, to enjoin defendants from producing an index that the copyright owners had declined to publish. The court was influenced by the plaintiff's unwillingness to publish a work like that produced by defendants, even though the plaintiff's unwillingness may have stemmed from a desire to protect its own derivative works. Cf. Roy Export Co. Estab. of Vaduz v. CBS, 503 F.Supp. 1137, 1146 n.5 (S.D.N.Y. 1980), ("[I]f the Roxbury court did consider harm to the potential market of derivative work to be irrelevant to a determination of the availability of the fair use defense, . . . we disagree . . . ."), aff'd, 672 F.2d 1095 (2d Cir.1982). Similarly, in Time, Inc. v. Bernard Geis Assocs., 293 F.Supp. 130 (S.D.N.Y. 1968), the owner of copyright in the Zapruder photographs of the Kennedy assassination denied permission to use the pictures. The denial did not come out of any antidissemination motive (e.g., to restrain criticism of the Warren Commission), but rather out of a desire to exploit the photographs economically. While there may have been some impropriety in plaintiff's plans for "monopolizing" the films, see Goldstein, supra note 39, at 986-88, 1035-55, it is preferable to view the market failure in Geis as not involving an antidissemination motive. The case is better viewed as involving an externality or nonmonetizable interest. See infra text accompanying notes 163-75.
[FN193]. This is what appeared to occur in the Benny case. See infra notes 221 & 223.
[FN194]. See 17 U.S.C. § 107(1) (Supp. IV 1980).
[FN195]. See id. § 107(3).
[FN196]. See id. § 107(4).
[FN197]. See Loew's, Inc. v. CBS, 131 F.Supp. 165, 184-85 (S.D.Cal. 1955), aff'd sub. nom. Benny v. Loew's, Inc. 239 F.2d 532 (9th Cir.1956), aff'd per curiam by an equally divided Court sub nom. CBS v. Loew's, Inc., 356 U.S. 43 (1958).
[FN198]. See also WXIA-TV v. Duncan, 8 Med.L.Rptr. 2075, 2079 n.9 (N.D.Ga. 1982) (issue of whether "plaintiff[] [television station's] copyright market inherently excludes" use in question held relevant to market impact factor of fair use).
[FN199]. Often the balancing concept employed in the cases is more diffuse than that applied in the second part of the fair use test set forth here. This Second Circuit statement is fairly typical: "The fair use doctrine offers a means of balancing the exclusive rights of a copyright holder with the public's interest in dissemination of information affecting areas of universal concern, such as art, science and industry." Wainwright Securities Inc. v. Wall Street Transcript Corp., 558 F.2d 91, 94 (2d Cir.1977). For examples of the courts' assessments of injury and benefit see Meeropol v. Nizer, 560 F.2d 1061 (2d Cir.1977), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1013 (1978); Rosemont Enters., Inc. v. Random House, Inc., 366 F.2d 303 (2d Cir.1966), cert. denied, 385 U.S. 1009 (1967). Some cases do directly weigh the copyright owner's loss against the public benefit, but even there it is unclear at what stage weighing becomes relevant. See, e.g., Time, Inc. v. Bernard Geis Assocs., 293 F.Supp. 130 (S.D.N.Y. 1968), discussed supra note 192.
[FN200]. Only the social value of those parts of defendant's work that need to use plaintiff's work is relevant here. It is necessary to evaluate not just the value of defendant's work, but also whether he needed to use plaintiff's work to achieve that value. See Roy Export Co. Estab. of Vaduz v. CBS, 503 F.Supp. 1137, 1144 (S.D.N.Y. 1980) (in assessing the purpose and character of defendant CBS's use, "[t]he jury could reasonably have concluded that if . . . it was essential to proper coverage of [Charlie] Chaplin's death that some film clips be shown, the showing of excerpts from films in the public domain would have been sufficient, and that CBS's decision to broadcast the offending version was motivated by commercial rather than educational considerations"), aff'd, 672 F.2d 1095, 1100 (2d Cir.1982) (assessing defendant's claim of a first amendment privilege in the copyright field) ("The showing of copyrighted [Chaplin] films was not essential to CBS's news report of Charlie Chaplin's death or to its assessment of his place in history; public domain films were available for the purpose, and the public is already generally familiar with his work."). See also Walt Disney Prods. v. Air Pirates, 581 F.2d 751, 756- 59 (9th Cir.1978) (evaluation of "necessity" in parody situations), cert. denied, 493 U.S. 1132 (1979); Meeropol v. Nizer, 560 F.2d 1061, 1071 n.14 (2d Cir.1977) ("necessity for verbatim copying"), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1013 (1978). See also Denicola, supra note 39, at 306-13 (necessity in the first amendment context).
[FN201]. In Martin Luther King, Jr. Center for Social Change, Inc. v. American Heritage Prods., 508 F.Supp. 854 (N.D.Ga. 1981), defendant corporation had marketed plastic busts of Dr. King, using the name of the Center for Social Change and using excerpts from Dr. King's copyrighted speeches in its advertisements and other materials. In rejecting the defendant's claim of fair use, the court noted that there was no "public interest consideration . . . present in this case. . . . Defendants' use of substantial passages from Dr. King's creative works was purely to induce consumers to buy the plastic busts and to convey the [false] impression that the Center approved of the product. This is not a 'fair use."' Id. at 861. See also Amana Refrigeration, Inc. v. Consumers Union of the United States, Inc., 431 F.Supp. 324, 326 (N.D. Iowa 1977) (deceptive use of quotations), discussed supra note 141. This consideration may also help to explain the court's decision in Walt Disney Prods. v. Air Pirates, 581 F.2d 751 (9th Cir.1978), cert. denied, 493 U.S. 1132 (1979), for the value of the defendants' depiction of "counter- cultural" lifestyle's may have been difficult for the court to perceive. This illustrates one danger of relying on a court's subjective measures of value.
[FN202]. See generally A. Latman & R. Gorman, supra note 19, at 473-75 (suggesting that a "'public interest' factor outweighing all others" may be developing that is "arguably bubbling under the surface of cases involving new technology").
[FN203]. See Bleistein v. Donaldson Lithographing Co., 188 U.S. 239 (1903). In Bleistein, Justice Holmes wrote: "It would be a dangerous undertaking for persons trained only to the law to constitute themselves final judges of the worth of pictorial illustrations, outside of the narrowest and most obvious limits." Id. at 251. See also Light, supra note 182, at 635-36 (a test for fair use should not allow a court to make literary evaluations of parodies and satires).
[FN204]. See Bleistein v. Donaldson Lithographing Co., 188 U.S. 239, 251- 52 (1903).
[FN205]. See supra text accompanying notes 89-92.
[FN206]. Whether the privilege [of fair use] may justifiably be applied to particular materials turns initially on the nature of the materials, e.g., whether their distribution would serve the public interest in the free dissemination of information and whether their preparation requires some use of prior materials dealing with the same subject matter. Consequently, the privilege has been applied to works in the fields of science, law, medicine, history and biography. Rosemont Enters., Inc. v. Random House, Inc., 366 F.2d 303, 307 (2d Cir.1966) (citation omitted), cert. denied, 385 U.S. 1009 (1967).
[FN207]. See, e.g., Time, Inc. v. Bernard Geis Assocs., 293 F.Supp. 130, 146 (S.D.N.Y. 1968) ("There is a public interest in having the fullest information available on the murder of President Kennedy. [Defendant] Thompson did serious work on the subject and has a theory entitled to public consideration."). See also supra notes 170-73 and accompanying text.
[FN208]. It can be argued that entertainment has a social value as worthy of protection pro tanto as any other--which is the position taken by this Article--or that entertainment uses have no value entitled to fair use protection, see infra note 210, or that its value is not susceptible to judicial appraisal, Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 480 F.Supp. 429, 452 (C.D.Cal. 1979) (refusing to disqualify copyrighted "New Mickey Mouse Club" episodes from fair use treatment despite an unwillingness to evaluate their social merit), rev'd in part and remanded, 659 F.2d 963 (9th Cir.1981), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982). Cf. Stanley v. Georgia, 394 U.S. 557, 566 (1969) (for first amendment purposes, "[t]he line between the transmission of ideas and mere entertainment is much too elusive for this Court to draw, if indeed such a line can be drawn at all").
[FN209]. Thus, the Second Circuit has seen social value in humor. See Elsemere Music, Inc. v. NBC, 623 F.2d 252, 253 & n.1 (2d Cir.1980) (per curiam) (emphasis added): [I]n today's world of often unrelieved solemnity, copyright law should be hospitable to the humor of parody . . . . A parody is entitled at least to 'conjure up' the original. Even more extensive use would still be fair use, provided the parody builds upon the original, using the original as a known element of modern culture and contributing something new for humorous effect or commentary. In the Betamax case, the Court of Appeals for the Ninth Circuit refused to base its holding of no fair use on the mere fact that the challenged uses served entertainment purposes. Although the Ninth Circuit noted that "there seems to be some indication that the scope of fair use is greater when informational type works, as opposed to more creative products, are involved," and that "[i]f a work is more appropriately characterized as entertainment, it is less likely that a claim of fair use will be accepted," Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 659 F.2d 963, 972 (9th Cir.1981) (footnote omitted), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687), the court's opinion did consider the entertainment to be of some value and took that value into account pro tanto in making its fair use determination. Id. at 971.
[FN210]. In Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer Inc. v. Showcase Atlanta Coop. Prods., Inc., 479 F.Supp. 351 (N.D.Ga. 1979), the owners and creators of "Scarlett Fever," a musical play based on Gone With The Wind, argued that their use of the copyrighted material was a parody or satire protected by fair use. The court rejected this contention, reasoning, inter alia, that in order to constitute the type of parody eligible for fair use protection, parody must do more than merely achieve comic effect. It must also make some critical comment or statement about the original work which reflects the original perspective of the parodist--thereby giving the parody social value beyond its entertainment function. Id. at 357 (footnote omitted). The court in Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer took this position because it believed that "[o]therwise, any comic use of an existing work would be protected" from liability via the fair use doctrine. Id. However, recognizing that entertainment has social value would not entitle all comic works to immunity from liability, as the court supposed; under a market-oriented approach, fair use would not be available unless there were justification for departing from the market. Without that market failure, no amount of social value should justify free use. See supra notes 89-91 and accompanying text. It is true that a lack of critical comment or perspective should militate against fair use, but the reason is not that such work lacks all social value. Rather, if an alleged "parody" fails to give audiences a new opinion of the copyrighted work, fair use may be barred because there is no market failure, i.e., because there is nothing to indicate that the copyright holder would have refused to license this use of his work. See supra notes 89-91 and accompanying text. In sum, the holding of the Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer court can be squared with the view advanced by this Article, that entertainment is a valuable use entitled pro tanto to fair use protection, if it is recognized that the court was using the language of social value to address whether a market failure appeared. Such an interpretation of Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer fits the facts of the case: there was no suggestion that the holders of copyright interests in Gone With The Wind objected to defendant's production in order to prevent criticism of the famous work from reaching the public or had any other antidissemination motive. Rather, the inference was that plaintiffs' were acting to protect their rights to license similar derivative works of their own. See 479 F.Supp. at 360-61. Since no market failure appeared, fair use was appropriately denied.
[FN211]. Some courts appear to award entertainment a social value, but weigh it less heavily in the fair use balance than other uses. The Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals arguably took this position in the Betamax case, finding home television recording to be of some value but of less importance than the "serious damage to medical science" that concerned the Williams & Wilkins court. Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 659 F.2d 963, 972 (9th Cir.1981), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687).
[FN212]. Entertainment is more likely to be able to recapture its social value in receipts than are the typical objects of fair use solicitude such as scholarship, and the monetary marketplace measures are likely to be more suitable gauges of the value of entertainment. See supra text accompanying notes 163-75. The courts often conflate the issues of whether a use encounters market failure and whether it has social value. See, e.g., Martin Luther King, Jr. Center for Social Change, Inc. v. American Heritage Prods., Inc., 508 F.Supp. 854, 861 (N.D.Ga. 1981) ("Although the fact that a use of a work is for commercial gain will not automatically preclude a finding of 'fair use,' generally fair use will be more readily recognized where the defendant's use is for educational, historical, or scientific purposes.").
[FN213]. To satisfy the first element of the fair use test presented herein, market failure must be shown. See supra notes 89-91 and accompanying text.
[FN214]. The presence of injury makes it more difficult to satisfy the second and third elements of the fair use test presented herein. See supra notes 92-103 & 104-124 and accompanying text.
[FN215]. "Whether an author or publisher reaps economic benefits from the sale of a biographical work . . . has no bearing on whether a public benefit may be derived from such a work." Rosemont Enterprises, Inc. v. Random House, Inc., 366 F.2d 303, 307 (2d Cir.1966), cert. denied, 385 U.S. 1009 (1967).
[FN216]. See M. Nimmer, supra note 97, § 13.05[A][4], at 13-64 to 13-65; Triangle Publications v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers, Inc., 626 F.2d 1171, 1177 (5th Cir.1980).
[FN217]. See, e.g., Wainwright Secs. Inc. v. Wall Street Transcript Corp., 558 F.2d 91, 93-94, 96 (2d Cir.1977) (enjoining weekly newspaper that had regularly abstracted plaintiff's copyrighted research reports, and had advertised the availability of such abstracts as one of its strong selling points), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1014 (1978); Meeropol v. Nizer, 560 F.2d 1061, 1069-71 (2d Cir.1977) (reversing summary judgment for defendants who used plaintiff's copyrighted letters without permission in book about plaintiff's parents), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1013 (1978). The court in Meeropol noted that "[a]lthough these letters represent less than one percent of [defendant's book], the letters were prominently featured in promotional material for the book," 560 F.2d at 1071 (footnote omitted), and "whether the book is bought because it contains the Rosenberg letters" may be considered, id. at 1071 n.14. See also Time, Inc. v. Bernard Geis Assocs., 293 F.Supp. 130 (S.D.N.Y. 1968) (plaintiff's motion for summary judgment denied on grounds of fair use where defendant author used sketches of copyrighted Zapruder films of Kennedy assassination as part of book criticizing the Warren Commission). The court in Geis considered the question of audience motivation quite relevant. In an opinion granting fair use treatment, the court found that "[t]he Book is not bought because it contained the Zapruder pictures." 293 F.Supp. at 146.
[FN218]. The more that is taken from the copyrighted work, the more likely is defendant's work to substitute for the original, so that the amount of the taking is relevant to injury. One of the fair use factors listed in the statute is "the amount and substantiality of the portion used in relation to the copyrighted work as a whole." 17 U.S.C. § 107(3) (Supp. IV 1980). In the Betamax case compare the Ninth Circuit's view of the substantiality criterion, Universal City Studios., Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 659 F.2d 963, 973 (9th Cir.1981) ("'excessive copying precludes fair use"'; lack of market injury is "'immaterial"') (relying, inter alia, on the Benny case, see infra note 221), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687) with that of the district court, 480 F.Supp. 429, 454-56 (C.D.Cal. 1979) ("the substantiality factor is inextricably bound with the issue of harm"). The substantiality criterion is also relevant to market failure analysis, for with less substantial takings the impact of transaction costs on the market is likely to be greater and the amount of injury is likely to be less. See supra notes 31 (fair use factors) & 155-59 (transaction costs) and accompanying text.
[FN219]. Compare New York Times v. Roxbury Data Interface, Inc., 434 F.Supp. 217 (D.N.J. 1977) (harm to plaintiff from loss of potential derivative market for Times index insufficient to bar defendant's production of index) with Roy Export Co. Estab. of Vaduz v. CBS, 503 F.Supp. 1137 (S.D.N.Y. 1980) (harm to derivative market for Chaplin film biographies, which plaintiff had already entered, argues against fair use treatment), aff'd, 672 F.2d 1095 (2d Cir.1982), both discussed supra note 192.
[FN220]. This is also the view taken by the court in Roy Export Co. Estab. of Vaduz v. CBS, 503 F.Supp. 1137, 1145-46 & n.5 (S.D.N.Y. 1980), aff'd, 672 F.2d 1095 (2d Cir.1982). See also Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer v. Showcase Atlanta Coop. Prods., Inc., 479 F.Supp. 351, 360-61 (N.D.Ga. 1979) (discussed supra note 188). As indicated by WXIA-TV v. Duncan, P. Med. L. Reptr. 2075, 2078-80 (N.D.Ga. 1982), a court should factually determine whether plaintiff does exploit or could exploit the market tapped by defendant. Antidissemination motives (e.g., the satire cases) or conflicts of interest (e.g., the WXIA case) may remove a use from potential exploitation by the copyright owner.
[FN221]. A focus on this often neglected fact may clarify one source of persistent confusion in this area: the extent to which a finding of "no injury" should itself justify fair use. In the famous Benny case, Loew's, Inc. v. CBS, 131 F.Supp. 165 (S.D.Cal. 1955), aff'd sub nom. Benny v. Loew's, Inc., 239 F.2d 532 (9th Cir.1956), aff'd per curiam by an equally divided Court sub nom. CBS v. Loew's, Inc., 356 U.S. 43 (1958), Jack Benny produced a fifteen-minute television skit that burlesqued the movie "Gaslight." He borrowed the movie's characters, plot development, setting, and even an appreciable amount of its dialogue. The district court held that the burlesque was an infringement, stating, inter alia, that [t]he mere absence of competition or injurious effect upon the copyrighted work will not make a use fair. The right of a copyright proprietor to exclude others is absolute and if it has been violated the fact that the infringement will not affect the sale or exploitation of the work or pecuniarily damage him is immaterial. Id. at 184 (emphasis added). However, the Benny court discussed only the effect of defendant's use on plaintiff's "sale or exploitation" to customers other than defendant himself, a factor that we might call "competitive injury." There is another potential type of injury: the loss of what defendant himself might pay to use plaintiff's work in his own projects, which we might call "building block injury." The mere absence of competitive injury should not justify fair use, not only because of the market failure requirement, but also because sufficient building block injury may be present to cause substantial injury to incentives. Building block injury will be absent only with complete market failure between copyright owner and user. After Benny lost the case, "trade rumour" reported that the copyright owners licensed Benny to use the material for $100,000. Netterville, Copyright and Tort Aspects of Parody, Mimicry and Humorous Commentary, 35 S.Cal.L.Rev. 225, 233 (1962). This suggests both that despite the burlesque form of the use, see supra text accompanying notes 193-98, there was no market failure, and that the "building block" receipts were substantial. See infra note 223. Infringement rather than fair use was the proper result. The court's language suggesting there was "no injury" is thus somewhat deceptive.
[FN222]. This calculation is consistent with the successful copyright plaintiff's ability to recover profits as well as damages to the extent they do not overlap. See 17 U.S.C. § 504(b) (1976).
[FN223]. See, e.g., Northwestern Bell Tel. Co. v. Bedco of Minn., Inc., 501 F.Supp. 299, 300 (D.Minn. 1980) (defendant soliciting advertising and listings for new yellow pages directory sent prospective advertisers photocopies of such businesses' listings in the copyrighted Northwestern Bell yellow pages; preliminary injunction granted). The court in Northwestern Bell noted: "[W]hat a subsequent compiler cannot do is copy from an already copyrighted directory and save himself the labor and expense incurred by the prior compiler." Id. at 302 (quoting Southwestern Bell Tel. Co. v. Nationwide Indep. Directory Serv., Inc., 371 F.Supp. 900, 906 (W.D.Ark. 1974)). In two leading companion cases, a television parody of the movie "Gaslight" that used most of that movie's plot elements was held an infringement, while fair use was granted to a parody of "From Here to Eternity" that depended less on the movie's own plot lines for interest. Compare Loew's, Inc. v. CBS, 131 F.Supp. 165, 170-71 n.9 (S.D.Cal. 1955), aff'd sub nom. Benny v. Loew's, Inc., 239 F.2d 532 (9th Cir.1956), aff'd per curiam by an equally divided Court, 356 U.S. 43 (1958) ("Gaslight"), with Columbia Pictures Corp. v. NBC, 137 F.Supp. 348, 350-58 (S.D.Cal. 1955) ("From Here to Eternity"). As mentioned supra note 221, the infringers of "Gaslight" must have considered the substantial building blocks borrowed from the movie to be of value; they reportedly purchased a license, after loss of the case, at a price of $100,000.
[FN224]. See, e.g., Cohen, supra note 146, at 45, 50-51.
[FN225]. See infra notes 230-33 and accompanying text.
[FN226]. See Cohen, supra note 146 at 43, 51-52, and sources cited therein; infra note 235.
[FN227]. Professor Latman suggested: [T]he tests [for fair use] may perhaps be summarized by: importance of the material copied or performed from the point of view of the reasonable copyright owner. In other words, would the reasonable copyright owner have consented to the use? At times, custom or public policy defines what is reasonable. Latman Study, supra note 102, at 15.
[FN228]. See, e.g., M. Nimmer, supra note 97, § 13.05, at 13-55 (1980).
[FN229]. This section discusses several types of consent. Apparent consent asks whether an individual copyright owner seems to have given his actual consent. "Likely" or "probable" consent (custom) asks whether an individual copyright owner, if asked, would give his consent. Hypothetical consent under the second branch of the fair use test asks if a copyright owner who was offered a perfect market price would consent. Each type of consent provides a mode of structuring the inquiry into whether social welfare is served by a transaction, so each is relevant to the second branch of the fair use test. In addition, facts that suggest the presence of apparent and likely consent indicate that little would be gained by insistance on a market bargain, so that they are relevant to the first part of the fair use test and, because consent indicates there is no injury to the owner, to the third part of the test as well. Apparent and likely consent thus serve as illustrations unifying the three parts of the test.
[FN230]. See Karll v. Curtis Publishing Co., 39 F.Supp. 836 (E.D.Wis. 1941) (eight lines of a song written by a fan of the Green Bay Packers quoted in magazine articles about the team; songwriter's complaint against the magazine dismissed on grounds of fair use). The court stated, inter alia: "When the plaintiff dedicated the song to the Green Bay Packers, by implication at least he consented to a reasonable use thereof associated with the Packers." Id. at 837. See also American Inst. of Architects v. Fenichel, 41 F.Supp. 146 (S.D.N.Y. 1941) (publisher of booklet of forms sued defendant who made 6 copies of one form apparently for use in architectural business; cover of the booklet stated: "The Institute's forms [are] intended for use in actual practice . . . and . . . may be drawn upon by architects in improving their own forms . . ."; summary judgment awarded to defendant on grounds of fair use). Note that in both Karll and Fenichel, apparent consent was only one of several factors relied upon.
[FN231]. As Dean Prosser has written: Consent to an act is simply willingness that it shall occur. Actual willingness . . . will prevent liability . . . even though the plaintiff has done nothing to manifest it to the defendant. But the converse is also true, that a manifestation of consent, upon which the defendant may reasonably rely, will be equally effective even though there is no willingness in fact. In our society we must perforce rely upon the overt words and acts of others, rather than upon their undisclosed minds . . . . W. Prosser, supra note 99, at 101 (footnotes omitted).
[FN232]. Most such owners will probably have intentions consistent with their actions, and seeking consent of the already-willing is wasteful.
[FN233]. A fair use holding here also respects the reliance interests that equity concepts of fairness have long recognized. The goal of providing incentives to encourage economically desirable behavior is relevant to the legal import of reliance in contexts other than fair use as well. See, e.g., Posner, supra note 33, at 67-70 (reliance in the contract context).
[FN234]. Among the fair use factors listed in § 107 are "the amount and substantiality of the portion used in relation to the copyrighted work as a whole," and "the effect of the use upon the potential market for or value of the copyrighted work." 17 U.S.C. § 107(3) & (4) (1976). The smaller the amount taken and the smaller the economic impact, the more likely consent would appear to be.
[FN235]. Fair use has sometimes been described as that which is "reasonable and customary." Note, 15 S.Cal.L.Rev. 249, 250 (1942); Latman Study, supra note 102, at 7. See also Shapiro, Bernstein & Co. v. P.F. Collier & Son Co., 26 U.S.P.Q. (BNA) 40, 42 (S.D.N.Y. 1934); MacMillan Co. v. King, 223 F. 862 (D.Mass. 1914). It is likely that the mass of fair use situations go unlitigated because owners willingly tolerate customary uses. A newspaper review that summarizes the plot of a reviewed play provides one classic example. Though widely presumed to be fair use, it is not a focus of much litigation itself. Presumably playwrights do consent to this use. Similarly, most scholars actively want their ideas to become part of the dialogue in their fields, even though participation in such dialogue might require them to tolerate colleagues quoting from and summarizing the expression of their copyrighted work. Thus, in scholarly fields and reviews--two areas of fair use mentioned specifically by § 107--actual subjective consent is probably quite common. Custom may yield some information about the dominant expectations and incentives of a typical copyright owner in a given milieu and may suggest whether copyright owners similarly situated to the plaintiff in a given case would consent to a contested use. It is thus revealing on the issue of whether a typical copyright owner would consent. Also, disturbing the pattern of custom can be expensive. We have already seen, however, that while custom may be suggestive of fair use treatment, it cannot and should not be a sufficient basis for fair use standing alone. See supra notes 122-24 and accompanying text. Inter alia, circumstances that justified the custom may change, and silence on the part of copyright owners does not invariably signal willing acquiescence.
[FN236]. Beneficial effects can take many forms. For example, defendant's work can provide publicity for the original. See, e.g., Karll v. Curtis Publishing Co., 39 F.Supp. 836, 837 (E.D.Wis. 1941): [I]t is very difficult to see how the value of the song could in any manner have been diminished by the article in question. Undoubtedly many thousands who read the article became aware for the first time of the existence of a musical composer by the name of Eric Karll [plaintiff]. See also Liebowitz, supra note 64, at 9-11. It has already been noted that copyright owners might be unwilling to license reviewers to produce potentially negative reviews, and that the presence of this possibility favors a grant of fair use when reviews are at issue. In addition, where the reviewers produce positive results for the owner, consent would appear likely. See Professor Latman's discussion of Karll and of the publicity value generally arising from reviews and criticism of scholarly works in A. Latman, The Copyright Law: Howell's Copyright Law Revised and the 1976 Act 205 (5th ed. 1979). See also G. Ricordi & Co. v. Mason, 201 F. 182, 183 (C.C.S.D.N.Y. 1911) (publicity value of defendant's work noted; motion for preliminary injunction denied), and 201 F. 184 (S.D.N.Y. 1912) (plaintiff's bill dismissed), aff'd, 210 F. 277 (2d Cir.1913); Latman Study, supra note 102, at 7 n.14. However, the market failure aspect of reviews is present whether or not the review turns out to be favorable. Otherwise, the copyright owner's market right might be used as leverage to obtain unwarranted positive reviews. Where the primary function of defendant's work is to give increased access to plaintiff's work, this increased access may bring a benefit to plaintiff or at least indicate the noncompetitive relationship between the two works. See New York Times v. Roxbury Data Interface, Inc., 434 F.Supp. 217 (S.D.N.Y. 1977) (defendant's index that was compiled from the New York Times Index, held to be fair use and thus not violative of copyright in the New York Times Index). Among the other factors the Roxbury Data court found relevant was the noncompetitive nature of the two works: The effect of defendants' personal name index on the market for the Times Index appears slight. Since defendants' index carries citations only to the New York Times Index, defendants' index is useless unless its user has access to the Times Index, from which he will be directed to the articles appearing in the New York Times . . . . [P]urchase of defendants' index in no way supersedes the need for plaintiffs' index . . . . Id. at 223-24. This sensitivity to the economic relation between works is consistent with a general sensitivity to the function of works. See the discussion of function in M. Nimmer, supra note 97, at § 13.05[B], at 13-65 to 13-72.
[FN237]. Traditionally, liability for copyright infringement has been found where copyrighted works are used in ways that compete with their originals. However, two related goods need not be substitutes; they may also be "complements," such that production of one good makes the other more desirable. Substitutes and complements can be exemplified as follows: [B]utter and margarine are substitutes because a decrease in the price of butter will result in a decrease in the quantity demanded of margarine--many margarine eaters really prefer the "higher-priced spread." On the other hand . . . gin and tonic may be complements since a decrease in the price of gin may increase the quantity demanded of gin, thus increasing the quantity demanded of tonic since gin and tonic tend to be used together. E. Mansfield, supra note 65, at 149-50. Complements exhibit negative cross- elasticity of demand; that is, availability of a complement increases demand for the product. On the other hand, positive cross-elasticity is exhibited by substitutes; that is, availability of a substitute generally decreases demand for the product. Determination of whether goods are complements or substitutes is empirical, based on observation of market forces. Id. Complementarity should favor fair use. I am indebted to Warren F. Schwartz here.
[FN238]. See supra note 236.
[FN239]. See supra notes 98-100 and accompanying text.
[FN240]. As noted previously, if the costs of doing business (including transaction costs) exceed the anticipated benefits, business will not be done. The result may be that a socially useful work will not be produced. Consider in this regard Judge Breyer's discussion of the impact that the inconvenience of obtaining consent can have on a scientist's use of prior works. Breyer, The Uneasy Case for Copyright, supra note 63, at 316-18.
[FN241]. Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 480 F.Supp. 429, 452 (C.D.Cal. 1979) (citing Fried, Fair Use and the New Act, 22 N.Y.L.Sch.L.Rev. 497, 509 n.53 (1976-77)), rev'd. in part and remanded, 659 F.2d 963 (9th Cir.1981), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687).
[FN242]. See, e.g., Meeropol v. Nizer, 560 F.2d 1061, 1069-70 (2d Cir.1977), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1013 (1978); Encyclopaedia Britannica Educ. Corp. v. Crooks, 542 F.Supp. 1156, 1174 (W.D.N.Y. 1982) ("Fair use must be reasonable. . . . [I]t is not reasonable to drive plaintiffs from the educational television market."); Columbia Pictures Corp. v. NBC, 137 F.Supp. 348, 350-51 (S.D.Cal. 1955) (by implication).
[FN243]. The substantial injury hurdle embraces a broader category of injury than does the balancing element of the fair use test, and serves different purposes. See supra text accompanying notes 108-24.
[FN244]. See supra notes 150-54 and accompanying text, discussing the out- of-print problem in connection with market barriers.
[FN245]. See Triangle Publications, Inc. v. Knight-Ridder Newspapers, Inc., 626 F.2d 1171, 1176 n.4 (5th Cir.1980); Meeropol v. Nizer, 560 F.2d 1061 (2d Cir.1977), cert. denied, 434 U.S. 1013 (1978).
[FN246]. House Report, supra note 10, at 68-70, reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News at 5681-84. See supra notes 150-52 and accompanying text, discussing the Guidelines in the context of market barriers.
[FN247]. House Report, supra note 10, at 69, reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News at 5685. Such copying could have a significantly adverse effect on the copyright owner's market.
[FN248]. House Report, supra note 10, at 68, reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News at 5684 ("the purpose of the following guidelines is to state the minimum standards of educational fair use . . . there may be instance in which copying which does not fall within the guidelines . . . may nonetheless be permitted under the criteria of fair use"). That the Guidelines were arrived at through interest-group bargaining also suggests the appropriateness of a consent-based analysis.
[FN249]. Williams & Wilkins Co. v. United States, 487 F.2d 1345 (Ct.Cl. 1973), aff'd by an equally divided Court, 420 U.S. 376 (1975) (per curiam). The Court of Claims had reversed the trial court's decision that the United States was liable for infringement, 172 U.S.P.Q. (BNA) 670 (Ct.Cl. 1972).
[FN250]. Encyclopaedia Britannica Educ. Corp. v. Crooks, 447 F.Supp. 243, 250 (W.D.N.Y. 1978). The decision in Williams & Wilkins preceded the 1976 congressional revision of the Copyright Act, Pub.L.No. 94-553, 90 Stat. 2541 (codified as amended in 17 U.S.C. (1976 & Supp. IV 1980)). As part of the 1976 Act, and in response to the reaction of librarian groups following the commencement of the Williams & Wilkins suit, Congress enacted 17 U.S.C. § 108 (1976 & Supp. IV 1980), which provides a structure within which much library photocopying is legally permissable. A. Latman & R. Gorman, supra note 19, at 519-20. "Section 108(d) might be said to codify the rule in Williams & Wilkins.'' Nimmer, supra note 9, at 1056 n.21. Nimmer notes, however, that the impact of § 108(g)(2) is unclear. That subsection denies protection to "systematic reproduction" of a work, and appears to be responsive to market failure and injury concerns. Section 108 provides that "[n]othing in this section . . . in any way affects the right of fair use." 17 U.S.C. § 108(f)(4) (1976 & Supp. IV 1980). But the relationship between § § 107 and 108 is the subject of some debate. See, e.g., A. Latman & R. Gorman, supra note 19, at 519. Despite the statutory changes, "[t]he court's analysis in Williams & Wilkins . . . remains valid today as to questions left open by the new Act." Encyclopaedia Britannica, 447 F.Supp. at 251 n.8. But see Williams & Wilkins, 487 F.2d at 1359 (ambiguous meaning of "copy" under 1909 Act relevant to fair use finding). See also infra note 273.
[FN251]. Williams & Wilkins, 487 F.2d at 1349.
[FN252]. Id. at 1348.
[FN253]. Id. at 1349.
[FN254]. Id.
[FN255]. Id. ("[A]bout 12 percent of the requests came from private or commercial organizations, particularly drug companies.").
[FN256]. Id. "Both institutions normally restrict copying on an individual request to a single copy of a single article of a journal issue, and to articles of less than 50 pages." Id. at 1354.
[FN257]. Id. at 1362-63 and passim. Note that the libraries' self-imposed restrictions (e.g., a refusal to provide articles from recent and widely- available journals to certain users, id. at 1355) were important to the court's finding of fair use. Id. at 1354-56.
[FN258]. See supra notes 163-75 and accompanying text.
[FN259]. 487 F.2d at 1354. The court also stressed the "personal, individual focus" of the photocopying. Id. at 1355. Such personal uses may be more readily discouraged by transaction costs. See supra text accompanying notes 155-60.
[FN260]. 487 F.2d at 1356-57.
[FN261]. Id. at 1356 ("[t]he supply of reprints and back numbers is wholly inadequate"). See also id. at 1357 & n.17 (plaintiff itself gives notice that it does not stock back issues).
[FN262]. Id. at 1357.
[FN263]. Id. at 1371 (Cowen, C.J., dissenting): The court has bottomed its decision to a very large extent on its finding, which is not disputed, that medical science would be seriously hurt if the photocopying by defendant's libraries is entirely stopped. But the court goes further and concludes that a judgment for plaintiff would lead to this result. It is not altogether clear to me how the court arrives at the second conclusion, and I think it is based on unwarranted assumptions.
[FN264]. See the discussion of transaction costs supra notes 155-62 and accompanying text. See Goldstein, The Private Consumption of Public Goods: A Comment on Williams & Wilkins Co. v. United States, 21 Bull. Copyright Soc'y 204 (1974) (recognizing the transaction cost problem but arguing it should not have justified fair use in that case). In addition, the majority seemed to fear that a finding of infringement would lead courts in other contexts, via stare decisis, to enjoin photocopying. Williams & Wilkins, 487 F.2d at 1360. Judge Nichols, in dissent, suggested that such injunctions would not necessarily follow. Id. at 1386-87 (Nichols, J., dissenting). In any event, even were an injunction to issue, it might not permanently stop an activity--the prevailing party, on whose behalf the injunction issues, may be able to sell the enjoined party a right to continue his activity. See Stanford Note, supra note 121, at 248-49. A determination of whether such a market would evolve following an injunction is relevant to assessing substantial injury. See Calabresi & Melamed, supra note 38, at 1116.
[FN265]. Some of the duplication of effort inherent in such individual transactions might be reduced if the library made the bargaining arrangements, but even then the transaction costs might be prohibitively high. Thus, "[d]efendant suggested at trial that payment of compensation to plaintiff for photocopying its journals would create a continuing undue and oppressive administrative and financial burden on NLM and the NIH library." Williams & Wilkins, 487F.2d at 1384 (Cowen, C.J., dissenting). Whether or not the transaction costs would in fact have been "oppressive" was not fully resolved; in the opinion of Chief Judge Cowen, the record did not justify defendant's fears. Id. at 1384-85.
[FN266]. Williams & Wilkins, 487 F.2d at 1360-61. The potential role of licensing and clearinghouses has been explored by many scholars. See, e.g., M. Nimmer, supra note 97, § 13.05[E][4][e], at 13-90 to 13-92 (discussing a possible judicial role in the creation of compulsory licenses).
[FN267]. Williams & Wilkins, 487 F.2d at 1372, 1378-79 & n.12, 1384-86 (Cowen, C.J., dissenting).
[FN268]. Id. See also id. at 1385 n.17.
[FN269]. It did, however, consider whether a market cure might evolve if plaintiff's copyright were not enforced as to photocopies: "It has been suggested . . . that publishers now have the power to adopt the intermediate solution of charging more for subscriptions sold to libraries or other entities which engage regularly in photocopying." Id. at 1360 n.26 (emphasis added). The court placed this unevaluated and seemingly casual suggestion in a footnote rather than addressing the issue more directly and vigorously. If the copyright owners would be able to capture photocopy income even without a liability judgment, that would be relevant to determining what injury the owners would suffer from a fair use holding. Professor Demsetz has suggested that price discrimination is consistent with efficiency in markets for public goods. See Demsetz, supra note 48, at 300-06. See also Liebowitz, supra note 64, at 12-17 (discussing price discrimination in journals).
[FN270]. 487 F.2d at 1360. See also id. at n.24.
[FN271]. Id. at 1360 n.24. "The possible intermediate solutions are also of the pragmatic kind legislatures, not courts, can and should fashion." Id. at 1360.
[FN272]. Id.
[FN273]. "[U]nder [the 1909 statute] . . . we have the choice only of thumb's up or thumb's down, for the photocopying practice involved in this litigation, without any real Congressional guidance. Intermediate or compromise solutions are not within our authority." Id. (footnote omitted). But see M. Nimmer, supra note 97, § 13.05[E][4][e], at 13-82 to 13-86. In addition to the general limitations of copyright law that might affect other courts, the Court of Claims lacked the power to enjoin governmental libraries. 487 F.2d at 1346 n.1. See 28 U.S.C. § 1498 (1976 & Supp. IV 1980).
[FN274]. 487 F.2d at 1372 (Cowen, C.J., dissenting).
[FN275]. Id. at 1360, 1362-63.
[FN276]. Id. at 1356-57, 1362-63, and passim.
[FN277]. Id. at 1357-59.
[FN278]. Id. at 1359.
[FN279]. See supra text accompanying notes 92-103. Note, however, that the court declined to prescribe a general rule using balancing methodology: [O]ur holding rests upon this record which fails to show a significant detriment to plaintiff but does demonstrate injury to medical and scientific research if photocopying of this kind is held unlawful. We leave untouched, because we do not have to reach them, the situations where the copyright owner is shown to be hurt or the recipients (or their interests) would not be significantly injured if the reproductions were ruled to infringe. 487 F.2d at 1362-63. This is consistent with the Court of Claim's overall reluctance to state general rules in this case: [T]he conclusion that defendant's particular use . . . has been 'fair' rests upon all of the elements discussed [in a previous portion of the opinion] and not upon any one, or any combination less than all. We do not have to, and do not, say than any particular component would be enough . . . . Conversely, we do not have to, and do not, say that all the elements we mention are essential . . . . Id. at 1362.
[FN280]. Id. at 1359.
[FN281]. See the discussion of the substantial injury hurdle, supra text accompanying notes 104-24. The court found that the record failed to "show a serious adverse impact, either on plaintiff or on medical publishers generally, from the photocopying practices of the type of NIH and NLM." 487 F.2d at 1359 (emphasis added). The court was thus looking to the impact of its decision on the marketplace as a whole, which is consistent with the substantial injury hurdle. See supra text accompanying notes 115-24.
[FN282]. Whether the privilege may justifiably be applied to particular materials turns initially on the nature of the materials, e.g., whether their distribution would serve the public interest in the free dissemination of information and whether their preparation requires some use of prior materials dealing with the same subject matter. 487 F.2d at 1352-53 (quoting Rosemont Enters., Inc. v. Random House, Inc., 366 F.2d 303, 307 (2d Cir.1966)).
[FN283]. "There is no doubt in our minds that medical science would be seriously hurt if such library photocopying were stopped." Id. at 1356. See supra notes 260-75 and accompanying text.
[FN284]. 487 F.2d at 1357 n.19.
[FN285]. Certain uses are not within protected categories at all, of course. See generally 17 U.S.C. § 106 (1976).
[FN286]. See supra text accompanying notes 122-24.
[FN287]. The court put a burden of demonstrating detriment on the plaintiff. 487 F.2d at 1359. This Article has suggested that this burden should be placed onthe plaintiff only where the defendant has made a convincing showing that the market between owner and user is so unlikely to function properly that the assumptions underlying the statutory damage provisions are undermined. See supra notes 137-44 and accompanying text. The Court of Claim's allocation of the burden indeed arose in part from the court's perception that the situation failed to conform to any perfect market model. 487 F.2d at 1358-59. But the court's insufficient consideration of market structure left in doubt whether the market failure was sufficiently likely or severe to justify this crucial shift in burden.
[FN288]. See supra note 279.
[FN289]. Universal City Studios, Inc. v. Sony Corp. of America, 659 F.2d 963 (9th Cir.1981), modifying 480 F.Supp. 429 (C.D.Cal. 1979), cert. granted, 102 S.Ct. 2926 (1982) (No. 81-1687).
[FN290]. Id. at 970 (emphasis omitted).
[FN291]. Id. at 970 (quoting L. Seltzer, supra note 4, at 24).
[FN292]. Id. (quoting L. Seltzer, supra note 4, at 24 (emphasis omitted)).
[FN293]. Id. at 971, (quoting L. Seltzer, supra note 4, at 38 (emphasis omitted)).
[FN294]. Id. at 971.
[FN295]. 17 U.S.C. § 107 (Supp. IV 1980).
[FN296]. See House Report, supra note 10, at 65-74, reprinted in 1976 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News at 5678-88; Senate Report, supra note 26, at 61-67. See also the congressional debate regarding sound recordings, 117 Cong. Rec. 34, 748 (1971) (statement of Representative Kastenmeier) (child's home recording of broadcast of music for listening pleasure is fair use), quoted in Universal City Studios, Inc., 480 F.Supp. at 446.
[FN297]. The Ninth Circuit addressed the issue of home sound recordings in terms of an exemption potentially arising out of the Sound Recording Amendment of 1971. (The Ninth Circuit inquired whether, if such an exemption existed, it would apply to home video-tape recording. The court concluded that it would not.) However, such characterization is erroneous. Whether or not persons who make tape recordings of music at home are copyright infringers is an issue that cannot be resolved solely by reference to an exemption potentially arising out of the 1971 legislative history. See Nimmer, supra note 125, at 1505. Long before the Sound Recording Amendment of 1971, the copyright in musical compositions (including, e.g., musical scores) could be infringed by the making of unauthorized recordings. See § 1(e) of the Copyright Act of 1909, 35 Stat. 1075, codified and reenacted 1947, amended 1976. When Congress in 1971 expressed a belief that home audio recording "over the past 20 years" was not an infringement, Nimmer, supra note 125, at 1509 (quoting H.R.Rep. No. 987, 92nd Cong., 1st Sess. 7, reprinted in 1971 U.S. Code Cong. & Ad. News 1566, 1572), the only possible legal basis for that belief was fair use. Id. at 1509-11. See also remarks of Representative Kastenmeier, 480 F.Supp. at 446 (discussed in Nimmer, supra 125, at 1511-12). Thus it is fair use that must be applied if home audio recording is to be immune from liability, and such recording is clearly "an intrinsic use." Professor Nimmer argues that although "[c]ourts and commentators have assumed that audio home recording is beyond the reach of copyright laws," Nimmer, supra note 125, at 1505, such recording should be considered an infringement. In making this argument, he relies on Seltzer's view that intrinsic uses should not be granted fair use treatment. Id. at 1521-22. However, Professor Nimmer himself urges in support of his conclusion the practicality of various methods of payment, thus revealing an implicit concern with market cure. Id. at 1525- 34. Moreover, he intimates a willingness to accept an economic justification for fair use. See id. at 1530 n.88.
[FN298]. On the other hand, ordinary consumers are more likely to be deterred by transaction costs. See supra note 259.
[FN299]. See supra text accompanying notes 115-16.
[FN300]. See generally supra notes 88-124 and accompanying text.
[FN301]. 659 F.2d at 971. The Ninth Circuit also asserted that use of the Williams & Wilkins approach would undermine incentives, id. at 970, and that such an approach would put copyright holders "in the unenviable position of proving damage in a context in which extreme difficulty is acknowledged," id. at 971. This Article has suggested that a substantial injury hurdle and sensitive application of burdens of proof can avoid these dangers. See supra notes 104-24 & 135-48 and accompanying text. The Ninth Circuit noted that "home users assign economic value to their ability to have control over access to copyrighted works," and that "[t]he copyright laws would seem to require that the copyright owner be given the opportunity to exploit this market." 659 F.2d at 974. Without an exploration of market cures, however, it is unclear whether such opportunity could be exploited and what constitutes the "potential market" for the copyrighted works.
[FN302]. L. Seltzer, supra note 4, at 31.
[FN303]. Id. (emphasis omitted).
[FN304]. Seltzer himself does not develop his basic clause in this way, of course. See id. at 36 ("Fair use, if it is to have any coherent meaning, must by itself suggest to both creator and society that it is not part of the normal market." (emphasis in original)). Seltzer's ideal statute would not appear to direct a court to take into account the economic and structural context in which defendant's use appears. Rather, he suggests that the second clause of his ideal statute might read: "In determining whether the use made of a work in a particular case deprives its creator of such a reward, account should be taken first of the nature of the copyrighted work and then of the purpose, character, and extent of the use." Id. at 36 (emphasis omitted).
[FN305]. Id. at 27-28, 40.
[FN306]. Id. at 27-28.
[FN307]. Id.
[FN308]. See Universal City Studios, Inc., 480 F.Supp. at 446, 454, 468.
[FN309]. In the event of a criminal violation, the government would of course bear the transaction costs. However, criminal liability for infringement applies only to "[a]ny person who infringes a copyright willfully and for purposes of commercial advantage or private financial gain." 17 U.S.C. § 506(a) (1976).
[FN310]. See supra note 48.
[FN311]. Defendants in Universal City Studios, Inc. included, inter alia, the manufacturers of the Betamax videorecorder and of videorecording tapes. 659 F.2d at 964. See Stanford Note, supra note 121, at 257-62.
[FN312]. Universal City Studios, Inc., 659 F.2d at 976.
[FN313]. Query whether these remedies are within the court's own injunctive powers. See Stanford Note, supra note 121, at 261; supra notes 129-34 and accompanying text. Also, a court should consider the administrative costs of its own actions in deciding on what course to follow. If administrative costs are high in relation to the benefits expected, an attempt at market cure may be undesirable.
[FN314]. See Stanford Note, supra note 121, at 261-62; McCullaugh, Shock Vibrates through Industry, Billboard, Oct. 31, 1981, at 1. See also Demsetz, supra note 48, at 306 ("In many instances it may be possible to tie in the consumption of a second product with consumption of the collective good, and private incentives may very well exist for the production of the tied-in good because exclusion is possible."). Of course, further factual investigation would be necessary to know if such market cures would be practicable. See, e.g., McCullaugh, supra ("execution and administration" of hardware surcharge system viewed by some as "nightmarish").
[FN315]. Performing rights societies serve a similar function for musical works today, under judicial antitrust supervision. See A. Latman & R. Gorman, supra note 19, at 455-58.
[FN316]. Universal City Studios, Inc., 659 F.2d at 971. The Ninth Circuit accurately described the procedure while rejecting it.
[FN317]. 480 F.Supp. at 457-62. See also the district court's discussion of injunctive relief, id. at 463-69.
[FN318]. "[R]equiring copyright holders to sue individual home users might amount to a total exemption for the Betamax . . . ." Stanford Note, supra note 121, at 258.
[FN319]. 659 F.2d at 974-76.
[FN320]. It seemed to assume that such a cure was possible, however. See id. at 976-77. ("[D]amages or a continuing royalty . . . may very well be an acceptable resolution in this context."). Among the sources cited by the Ninth Circuit was the Stanford Note, supra note 121, which discussed methods of market restructuring. See 659 F.2d 966 nn.1,2. Explicit consideration of the possibility was necessary, to avoid misunderstandings and ridicule on the one hand, and, on the other, to avoid the danger of a complete cessation of use of the new technology. See supra note 124 (discussing popular reactions to the Ninth Circuit decision).
[FN321]. 659 F.2d at 976.
END OF DOCUMENT
Copr. © West 2001 No Claim to Orig. U.S. Govt. Works